logo

American Society of Civil Engineers Researhc Paper 2022

   

Added on  2022-10-12

74 Pages24243 Words14 Views
This is the author’s version of a work that was submitted/accepted for pub-
lication in the following source:
Chen, Le & Manley, Karen (2014) Validation of an instrument to mea-
sure governance and performance on collaborative infrastructure projects.
Journal of Construction Engineering and Management, 140.
This file was downloaded from: http://eprints.qut.edu.au/66871/
c© Copyright 2014 American Society of Civil Engineers (ASCE)
Notice: Changes introduced as a result of publishing processes such as
copy-editing and formatting may not be reflected in this document. For a
definitive version of this work, please refer to the published source:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0000834

1
Chen, L., and Manley, K. (2014). "Validation of an instrument to measure governance and
performance on collaborative infrastructure projects." Journal of Construction Engineering and
Management, Inpress.

Validation of an instrument to measure governance and
performance on collaborative infrastructure projects

Le Chen
1 and Karen Manley2
Abstract

Collaborative infrastructure projects use hybrid formal and informal governance structures to
manage transactions. Based on previous desk-top research, the authors identified the key
mechanisms underlying project governance, and posited the performance implications of the
governance (
Chen et al. 2012). The current paper extends that qualitative research by testing
the veracity of those findings using data from 320 Australian construction organisations. The
results provide, for the first time, reliable and valid scales to measure governance and
performance of collaborative projects, and the relationship between them. The results confirm
seven of seven hypothesised governance mechanisms; 30 of 43 hypothesised underlying
actions; eight of eight hypothesised key performance indicators; and the dual importance of
formal and informal governance. A startling finding of the study was that the implementation
intensity of informal mechanisms (non-contractual conditions) is a greater predictor of
project performance variance than that of formal mechanisms (contractual conditions).
Further, contractual conditions do not directly impact project performance; instead their
impact is mediated by the non-contractual features of a project. Obligations established under
the contract are not sufficient to optimise project performance.

CE Database subject headings: Procurement; Partnerships; Australia.

Author’s Keywords: Construction; Collaborative project; Project governance, Value for money;
Project performance.

1 Le Chen, Research Fellow, School of Civil Engineering and Built Environment, Science and Engineering
Faculty, Queensland University of Technology, S Block, Level 7, Room S724, Gardens Point campus , GPO
Box 2434, Brisbane, Qld 4001 Australia. E-mail:
le.chen@qut.edu.au.
2 Karen Manley, Associate Professor, School of Civil Engineering and Built Environment, Science and
Engineering Faculty, Queensland University of Technology, S Block, Level 7, Room S737, Gardens Point
campus , GPO Box 2434, Brisbane, Qld 4001 Australia. E-mail:
k.manley@qut.edu.au.

2
Introduction

Over the past decade, collaborative procurement models (CPMs) have been
increasingly used in many countries for delivering high value, complex infrastructure projects
in industrial sectors such as road, rail, water, energy, mining and defense (
Department of
Treasury and Finance 2009
; Love et al. 2011; Morwood et al. 2008; Scheepbouwer and
Humphries 2011
). A collaborative procurement model is designed to encourage relationships
between project participants in an effort to maximise outcomes. The rise in the use of
collaborative procurement reflects the increasing sophistication of construction projects to
deliver infrastructure and the need to manage high levels of complexity and uncertainty
(
Morwood et al. 2008). Examples of CPMs are project alliances; program alliances;
integrated project delivery (IPD); early contractor involvement (ECI); and traditional with
partnering. CPMs have delivered significant community, environmental and social outcomes
in conjunction with effective cost management and innovation (
Davis and Love 2011; Hauck
et al. 2004
; Love et al. 2010). See Kent and Becerik-Gerber (2010); Love et al. (2010);
Scheepbouwer and Humphries (
2011); and Lahdenperä (2012) for a description of these
delivery systems. The literature suggests that the alliances provide the most robust support of
collaboration (
Ross 2008), albeit with question marks over outcomes and the relatively high
cost of implementation (
Department of Treasury and Finance 2009).
The current paper focuses on Alliance-type procurement systems, which are currently
attracting considerable interest across America and Europe after recent extensive use in the
Australian context (
Kelly 2011). The governance of these collaborative projects falls into two
primary classes – formal and informal. Each project comprises distinct combinations of
formal and informal mechanisms and underlying actions (
Lahdenperä 2012; Love et al.
2010
). Formal governance comprises contractual incentives for clear and equitable risk
allocation (
Lahdenperä 2010; Love et al. 2011). Informal governance comprises non-

3
contractual incentives to enhance mutual trust, enable cooperation, facilitate open
communication and share knowledge (
Rahman and Kumaraswamy 2012). It is evident in the
literature that different combinations of formal and informal mechanisms are applied within
various transactional contexts (
Love et al. 2010; Scheepbouwer and Humphries 2011). For
example, high risk projects are likely to involve a greater concentration of informal
mechanisms, like relationship workshops, to encourage trust.

Empirical evidence has not yet been established to clearly identify what roles the two
classes of governance play in performance outcomes (
Department of Infrastructure and
Transport 2011
; Kelly 2011; Lenferink et al. 2012; Nyström 2008). This is despite calls from
prominent industry players (
Department of Treasury and Finance 2009). The paper responds
to this knowledge gap by addressing five research objectives:

1) To build a conceptual model showing the relationship between governance and
performance;

2) To verify the essential mechanisms which define formal and informal governance
for complex infrastructure delivery;

3) To verify the essential actions that underlie each mechanism;

4) To verify key performance indicators for collaborative infrastructure projects;

5) To investigate the association between project governance classes and project
performance.

Previous literature on the topic has presented limited statistically rigorous evidence
gathered by deductive means about the performance implications of collaborative
procurement mechanisms (
Eriksson and Westerberg 2011). Instead previous contributions
rely on inductive methods such as interviews (e.g.
Bresnen 2009; Davis and Love 2011;
Hauck et al. 2004
; Lenferink et al. 2012; Love et al. 2011; Love et al. 2010; Rose and Manley
2012
). The current study provides much-needed statistical evidence about the performance

4
implications of collaborative governance for infrastructure delivery. This extends the theory
building cycle into a deductive phase. The findings reported here provide a more
generalizable understanding of collaborative governance to maximise project outcomes,
compared to inductive methods.

Building the Conceptual Model

Project Governance

Infrastructure projects are usually characterised by a high level of durable transaction-
specific investment and a high degree of uncertainty (
Morwood et al. 2008). In line with the
perspective of transaction-cost economics (
Williamson 1979), the construction management
literature stresses the need to apply collaborative governance to manage the non-
marketability challenges associated with infrastructure project transactions where duration,
complexity and uncertainty are rapidly increasing (
Chan et al. 2010; Lahdenperä 2012; Love
et al. 2010
; Rahman and Kumaraswamy 2012).
In practice, collaborative infrastructure projects adopt hybrid governance structures
(
Lahdenperä 2012; Lenferink et al. 2012) comprising formal and informal mechanisms,
which utilise both market and hierarchical transactions (
Williamson 1991) to facilitate the
negotiation and execution of physical and human capital transactions (
Chan et al. 2010).
Formal mechanisms include market transactions through formal contracts and de-
personalized exchange (
Ferguson et al. 2005; Williamson 1991), and hierarchical transactions
through performance measurement and dispute resolution procedures (
Gulati and Singh
1998
). Formal governance mechanisms are largely independent of the specific people
involved, can specify outcomes (
Hoetker and Mellewigt 2009), and are suitable for
controlling physical capital, which is easily codified (written down) and transmitted (
Hoetker
and Mellewigt 2009
).

5
By comparison, informal mechanisms focus on relationships (
Hoetker and Mellewigt
2009
; Macneil 2000), and include people and social-based hierarchical relations for
enhancing mutual trust, open communication, cooperation and knowledge sharing (
Gulati and
Singh 1998
). Informal mechanisms are normally applied as non-contractual stimuli designed
to enable equitable allocation of risk through influencing the attitudes of individuals involved
in the transaction, and are tightly bound to the specific individuals and their relationships
(
Hoetker and Mellewigt 2009). Hence the outcomes of informal mechanisms largely depend
upon interactions between individual participants and cannot be pre-specified (
Hoetker and
Mellewigt 2009
). These mechanisms are most suitable for controlling human capital
transactions, which are idiosyncratic due to the tacit nature of the knowledge and the
cognitive context involved (
Williamson 1979).
Formal Mechanisms

A previous review of leading construction management literature by the authors
(
Chen et al. 2012) identified three essential mechanisms of formal governance: ‘collective
cost estimation’, ‘risk and reward sharing regime’, and ‘design integration’. These
mechanisms are described below prior to verifying that they are a valid measure of formal
governance.

Collective Cost Estimation

The cost of alliance projects are jointly estimated by an integrated team formed by the
owner, designer, contractor and other service providers during the Target Cost Estimate
(TCE) process (
Love et al. 2011). The parties come together to develop the scope of work,
define the time schedule, and agree on cost-reimbursable principles (
Morwood et al. 2008).
As an essential output of the TCE process, the target outturn cost (TOC) is developed to

6
represent the expected cost of the project’s scope at completion, including project specific
costs and overheads, as well as service providers’ profit margin and non-project related
corporate overheads (
Morwood et al. 2008). The TOC is used as the benchmark to assess
performance and to determine how risk and rewards are shared by the parties (
Department of
Infrastructure and Transport 2011
; Love et al. 2011). An actual outturn cost (AOC) close to
the TOC also demonstrates value for money (
Love et al. 2011).
ECI combines principles of Alliances and traditional Design and Build (DB) methods,
and uses a two stage arrangement to manage initial risks. The collective cost estimation is
primarily carried out in the collaborative stage, where the owner, contractor and designer
work together to develop the design, program, budget and risk allocation model (
Lenferink et
al. 2012
; Scheepbouwer and Humphries 2011). Alliance and ECI project structures are
tailored to the unique characteristics of a given project, where owners ensure price
competitiveness through selecting either one or multiple service provider teams to participate
in the scoping and pricing stage (
Lahdenperä 2010; Lenferink et al. 2012; Love et al. 2011;
Scheepbouwer and Humphries 2011
).
Engaging only one service provider team in the pricing stage has been found to enable
better development of a trustful and cooperative relationship between the owner and the
proponent (
Kelly 2011; Ross 2008). However, this approach is also criticized for lacking
sufficient incentive to achieve cost-effective pricing, which has been argued as the advantage
of the multiple team approach, since the later builds competitive tension between the
proponent teams (
Department of Infrastructure and Transport 2011). The choice of approach
depends largely on the transactional context of the specific project (
Lenferink et al. 2012;
Morwood et al. 2008
).

7
Risk and Reward Sharing Regime

The risk and reward sharing regime constitutes the foundation of collaborative
procurement’s commercial framework (
Chan et al. 2010; Lahdenperä 2012; Lenferink et al.
2012
). In alliance projects, this regime enables the parties (including the owner) to share
savings and overruns according to the set TOC. That is, any cost under- or over-run against
this TOC is split in pre-agreed, specified proportions (
Lahdenperä 2010; Love et al. 2011).
Normally, the owner takes 50% of both the gain (profit due to cost underruns) and pain (loss
due to cost overruns), and the remaining 50% is available to be split between the service
providers (
Department of Infrastructure and Transport 2011; Morwood et al. 2008).
Historically, most Alliance contracts cap the overall risk for each service provider at
the loss of the service provision fee, which means that even in the worst case scenario, the
service providers will still be reimbursed for the direct costs of the project (
Morwood et al.
2008
). The owner’s non-price objectives are represented by Key Result Areas (KRAs) such
as facility performance, safety, and timely completion, which are pre-agreed between the
owner and service providers, and measured and rewarded based on Key Performance
Indicators (KPIs) (
Department of Infrastructure and Transport 2011; Morwood et al. 2008).
In the case of ECI projects, the payment to the contractor is based on actual cost at an
agreed rate, plus an agreed amount for profit and overheads (
Scheepbouwer and Humphries
2011
). Similarly to project alliances, the contractor is financially rewarded for success in
some KRAs from a performance pool (
Edwards 2009).
Design Integration

Formal mechanisms are designed specifically to spur the parties to invest and
cooperate in joint design during the development phase, which is critical for innovation and
project success (
Lenferink et al. 2012; Love et al. 2010; Morwood et al. 2008). Through

End of preview

Want to access all the pages? Upload your documents or become a member.

Related Documents
Assessment of Collaborative Procurement Mechanisms in Construction
|5
|1623
|77