Drilling for Micro-Foundations of Human Capital-Based Competitive Advantages

Verified

Added on  2023/04/22

|16
|9420
|151
AI Summary
This article explores the micro-foundations of strategic capabilities and the importance of human capital as a source of sustained competitive advantage. It highlights the challenges associated with attracting, retaining, and motivating talented employees and outlines a research agenda for exploring cross-level components of human capital-based advantages.

Contribute Materials

Your contribution can guide someone’s learning journey. Share your documents today.
Document Page
http://jom.sagepub.com/
Journal of Management
http://jom.sagepub.com/content/37/5/1429
The online version of this article can be found at:
DOI: 10.1177/0149206310397772
2011 37: 1429 originally published online 22 February 2011Journal of Management
Russell Coff and David Kryscynski
Competitive Advantages
BasedInvited Editorial: Drilling for Micro-Foundations of Human Capital
Published by:
http://www.sagepublications.com
On behalf of:
Southern Management Association
can be found at:Journal of ManagementAdditional services and information for
http://jom.sagepub.com/cgi/alertsEmail Alerts:
http://jom.sagepub.com/subscriptionsSubscriptions:
http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:
http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:
http://jom.sagepub.com/content/37/5/1429.refs.htmlCitations:
What is This?
- Feb 22, 2011OnlineFirst Version of Record
- Feb 28, 2011OnlineFirst Version of Record
- Aug 19, 2011Version of Record>>
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Secure Best Marks with AI Grader

Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
Document Page
Drilling for Micro-Foundations of Human
Capital–Based Competitive Advantages
Russell Coff
University of Wisconsin–Madison
David Kryscynski
Emory University
From the origins of resource-based theory, scholars have emphasized the importance of human
capital as a source of sustained competitive advantage, and recently there has been great inter-
est in gaining a better understanding of the micro-foundations of strategic capabilities. Along
these lines, there is little doubt that heterogeneous human capital is often a critical underlying
mechanism for capabilities. Here, the authors explore how individual-level phenomena under-
pin isolating mechanisms that sustain human capital–based advantages but also create man-
agement dilemmas that must be resolved in order to create value. The solutions to these
challenges cannot be found purely in generic human resource policies that reflect best prac-
tices. These are not designed to mitigate idiosyncratic dilemmas that arise from the very attri-
butes that hinder imitation (e.g., specificity, social complexity, and causal ambiguity). The
authors drill down deeper to identify individual- and firm-level components that interact to
grant some firms unique capabilities in attracting, retaining, and motivating human capital.
This cospecialization of idiosyncratic individuals and organizational systems may be among the
most powerful isolating mechanism. The authors conclude by outlining a research agenda for
exploring cross-level components of human capital–based advantages.
Keywords: acquisition/strategic factor markets; knowledge management; resource-based
theory; strategic HRM
1429
Corresponding author: Russell Coff, University of Wisconsin–Madison, 4259 Grainger Hall, 975 University
Avenue, Madison, WI 53706, USA
Email: RCoff@bus.wisc.edu
Journal of Management
Vol. 37 No. 5, September 2011 1429-1443
DOI: 10.1177/0149206310397772
© The Author(s) 2011
Reprints and permission: http://www.
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
Special Issue:
Twenty Years of
Resource-Based Theory
Invited Editorial
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
1430 Journal of Management / September 2011
From the origins of the resource-based theory of the firm, scholars have emphasized the
importance of human capital as a source of sustained competitive advantage (Barney, 1991).
However, the underlying mechanisms tying human capital to competitive advantage have
not been fully developed. Recent calls to drill down to the “micro-foundations” of resources
and capabilities have highlighted the critical role of individuals in creating and sustaining
competitive advantages (Abell, Felin, & Foss, 2008; Felin & Hesterly, 2007; Teece, 2007).
As such, the more we drill down, the more we see that the micro-foundations of capabilities
are bolstered by human capital—that is, the knowledge skills and abilities of individual employ-
ees. Presumably, firms with superior human capital are better positioned to create resources
and capabilities characterized by asset specificity, social complexity, and causal ambiguity,
making them very difficult to imitate (Barney, 1991; Hall, 1993; Reed & DeFillippi, 1990).
While human capital may be at the root of many capabilities, the micro-foundations of
human capital management are not well developed (Coff, 1997). This lack of development
is concerning because, as we shall see, the very factors that make human capital inherently
hard to imitate may also make maximizing value through human capital a highly complex
and difficult challenge. Since valuable capabilities rely on individuals with idiosyncratic goals,
desires, and preferences who can choose whether to join, stay, or exert effort, our search for
solutions may also need to focus on individuals. As Foss (2011; this issue) points out, a more
detailed understanding of individuals and their interactions with each other and the firm may
help us to uncover how firms are better able to cope with the inherent dilemmas associated
with human capital–based competitive advantages.
Our primary thesis, then, is that human capital–based advantages require multilevel solu-
tions to address vexing challenges associated with attracting, retaining, and motivating talented
employees. As such, a human capital–driven advantage requires a set of capabilities and a
complementary set of unique individuals. We review the separate problems of attracting,
motivating, and retaining talented employees and highlight the multilevel nature of human
capital dilemmas as well as their possible solutions. In keeping with the goals of this special
issue, we also highlight fruitful opportunities for future research.
Human Capital and the Promise of Competitive Advantage
Early human capital theory focused on investment decisions that individuals face when
considering acquisitions of new knowledge or skills (Ashenfelter, 1978; Ashenfelter & Krueger,
1994; Becker, 1964; Griliches, 1977). Thus, we must define human capital at the micro
level—an individual’s stock of knowledge, skills, and abilities (hereafter, skills) that can be
increased through mechanisms like education, training, and experience (Becker, 1964). This
definition contrasts conceptualizations often utilized by strategy scholars that characterize
human capital as a unit-level resource (Ployhart & Moliterno, 2011). For convenience, we
refer to the firm-level aggregation of employee skills as firm-level human assets. As such,
the origins of human capital are inherently at the micro level despite a more macro focus in
the strategy literature on the aggregate human capital resources available to the firm (Hatch &
Dyer, 2004; Kor & Leblebici, 2005).
To focus our arguments, we first define human capital–based competitive advantage. Peteraf
and Barney (2003: 314) argue that “an enterprise has a competitive advantage if it is able to
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1431
create more economic value than the marginal (breakeven) competitor in its product market.”
By extension, a human capital–based advantage arises when this “greater economic value”
is attributable to the firm’s access to and utilization of employee knowledge, skills, and
abilities. Thus, for the present discussion, the critical path to human capital–based competi-
tive advantage requires attracting, retaining, and motivating employees with valuable human
capital at an economic discount relative to competitors.
Isolating Mechanisms and Human Capital
It is widely accepted that human capital holds promise as a source of sustainable advan-
tage since human assets are often valuable, rare, and imperfectly imitable (Barney, 1991;
Hall, 1993; Hatch & Dyer, 2004). Human capital is valuable for the unique abilities that
individuals can bring, and it can also be quite rare—particularly at high levels of specialized
expertise. Finally, to result in a sustained advantage, human capital must be associated with
isolating mechanisms that keep rivals at bay. Human capital–based advantages are often
linked to three key isolating mechanisms: firm-specificity, social complexity, and causal
ambiguity. These operate simultaneously at the firm level and the individual level in slightly
different ways, as we discuss below. It is worth underscoring that human capital derives its
strategic importance from idiosyncratic individual differences—again highlighting the need
for strong micro-foundations.
Firm-specificity is the extent to which individual assets are tailored for use in a single
firm (Williamson, 1975). The strategy literature often treats specificity as a requirement for
strategic assets (Amit & Schoemaker, 1993). Firm-specificity can serve as an isolating
mechanism since there is no market to bid up the price of these assets (Klein, Crawford, &
Alchian, 1978)—they cannot be deployed in other contexts. At the firm level, firm-specificity
describes the extent to which human assets are more valuable to the current firm than to
rivals. For individuals, firm-specificity may limit mobility since employees’ skills are less
valuable to other firms. Skills can be more or less firm-specific due to idiosyncratic attributes
(Becker, 1964) or due to complex combinations of general skills that lead to idiosyncratic
bundles of skills (Lazear, 2009).
Social complexity refers to the extent to which individual assets are embedded in highly
complex social systems (Barney, 1991). At the firm level, these socially complex systems
hinder the replication of human assets—systems that are more complex are harder to copy.
The resources might be quite valuable to competitors, but the complexity makes them very
difficult to copy. Additionally, as complexity increases, it becomes more difficult to extract
any single piece of the system without degrading value. In other words, the value of a single
employee’s human capital may be drastically reduced if plucked out of the particular com-
plex social system.
Causal ambiguity is the extent to which individual assets are difficult to link to organiza-
tional performance (Lippman & Rumelt, 1982; Reed & DeFillippi, 1990). At the firm level,
it may be hard to link human capital to performance. On the individual level, the importance
of tacit knowledge presents additional dilemmas precisely because it resides in the heads of
individuals (Felin & Hesterly, 2007). Tacit knowledge can be causally ambiguous both for
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Secure Best Marks with AI Grader

Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
Document Page
1432 Journal of Management / September 2011
managers and competitors. It is unclear who has the knowledge, or even which knowledge
is critical. Thus, causal ambiguity hinders rivals’ attempts to identify which aspects of a
firm’s human capital management routines to copy and which employees are most important
to hire away.
Generic Human Resource Systems Cannot Fully Explain Human Capital–Based
Advantages
Taken together, firm-specificity, social complexity and causal ambiguity provide three
mechanisms that may explain why human assets can be a key source of sustained advantage.
Accordingly, the strategic human resource (HR) management literature has continued a rich
tradition of prescribing HR systems and policies that enhance a firm’s human capital resources
(Arthur, 1994; Lado & Wilson, 1994). However, one could argue that these fully codified
solutions are easily understood and, thus, unlikely to offer sustained human capital advan-
tages on their own (Chadwick & Dabu, 2009). If so, we should generally expect these “best
practice” solutions to be strategically less relevant. In other words, these systems may help
firms increase efficiency given their chosen strategies, but the systems are chosen to fit with
a strategy rather than to provide sustained advantages in and of themselves.
Additionally, Becker and Huselid (2006) critique the strategic HR literature for its “black
box” approach to relating HR systems to firm performance. They explicitly call for more
theory and empirical analysis to open this black box and more carefully articulate the mecha-
nisms connecting HR systems to human capital–based advantages. We echo these concerns
and also suggest that an excessive focus on firm-level HR practices has obscured the inher-
ently multilevel nature of human capital (Ployhart & Moliterno, 2011). A more careful analy-
sis at the individual and firm levels reveals both varied sources of the isolating mechanisms
and underappreciated dilemmas created by these mechanisms.
Micro-Foundations and Human Capital–Based Dilemmas
While human capital is a promising source of sustained competitive advantage, the attri-
butes that make these resources so attractive also pose significant management dilemmas.
As Coff (1997) points out, unlike other types of resources, humans can quit, withhold effort,
and bargain for rents. To create and sustain superior human assets, managers must mitigate
challenges linked to (1) attracting and hiring critical employees, (2) retaining the best
employees, and (3) motivating employees. Successfully navigating these challenges provides
a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for a human capital–based competitive advantage.
In the following sections, we explore these challenges along with potential coping strategies.
A summary of our arguments is shown in Table 1.
Attracting Human Capital
Attraction dilemmas from isolating mechanisms. The first challenge on the road to a
human capital–based advantage is attracting and hiring employees with valuable human
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1433
capital. Doing so is challenging because individuals have unique mixes of human capital that
are difficult to observe and evaluate ex ante. As a result, human capital markets are imperfect
and laden with hazards. First, since firms cannot generally hire employees with firm-specific
human capital, they must seek individuals who have both the motivation and the ability to
acquire the desired firm-specific human capital once hired. As we see from the substantial
literature exploring employee selection challenges (e.g., Ployhart, 2006; Trank, Rynes, &
Bretz, 2002), identifying employees with this future potential can be especially difficult.
This difficulty is amplified when the focal skills are idiosyncratic to the firm and cannot be
observed ex ante.
Beyond hiring employees with the right skills and potential to learn, firms must also hire
employees who properly “fit” into the organization. Those who do not fit may not be as
motivated or productive and/or may quickly leave the firm (O’Reilly, Chatman, & Caldwell,
1991; Schneider, 1987). Hiring for fit can be especially challenging in firms with socially
complex human capital resources since individuals must internalize and adapt to the organi-
zational culture, identity, routines, norms, values, and so forth. For these complex systems to
work, employees need to cooperate and share knowledge. As Borgatti and Cross (2003) show,
however, the social costs of sharing and accessing valuable information may overshadow the
perceived value of cooperating—especially for employees who are not well integrated.
Additional hiring challenges arise from the classic “market for lemons” adverse selection
problem (Akerlof, 1970). Adverse selection happens when there is asymmetric information
in the market—that is, individuals know more about their skills than potential employers do.
As employers offer lower wages to mitigate the risk of hiring lemons, workers with excep-
tional human capital choose to avoid this job-switching penalty. Thus, job seekers will be
Table 1
Micro-Foundations of Human Capital Dilemmas and Solutions
Heterogeneity at the Individual Level as a
Dilemma Source of Management Dilemmas Potential Solution to the Dilemmas
Attraction Imperfect and asymmetric information exists
about individuals’ skills in labor markets.
There is uncertainty about employees’ ability and
willingness to invest in firm-specific skills.
It is hard to assess how well individuals will fit
into the social system.
Top employees may attract other high-quality
people to the firm.
Employees’ unique social networks may offer
better information and leads on prospective
workers (to better assess quality and fit).
Retention Employees’ external networks enhance mobility
(and turnover).
Individuals’ idiosyncratic contributions may be
unobservable, making it unclear who should be
retained.
Individual managers play a role in providing
quality supervision, recognition, and
structuring the work itself.
Leaders help to set norms that produce
satisfaction with coworkers.
Motivation Individuals vary in their contributions to team
production, and these are hard to observe and
reward.
People place unique values on rewards and
respond to incentives differently.
Role models espouse norms that others may
internalize even if incentives cannot be aligned.
Line managers know and reward (or punish) top
performers (or those who are not performing
adequately).
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
1434 Journal of Management / September 2011
disproportionately low-quality workers. Causal ambiguity can further exacerbate this lemons
problem by making it more difficult to identify how prospective employees may have con-
tributed to their prior employers’ successes. For example, applicants may misrepresent them-
selves by taking credit for others’ successes. Causal ambiguity will thwart efforts to verify
such claims.
These dilemmas highlight a very complicated attraction challenge—firms must attract
high-quality employees amid imperfect information about their skills, abilities, and fit with
the organization, while employees may offer incorrect or misleading information about their
own qualities. Firms often rely on crude signals, such as educational level, even though wide
variations in productivity remain (Delfgaauw & Dur, 2007; Spence, 1973). Thus, the ability
to identify individuals with valuable human capital, using incomplete information, may be
quite central to competitive advantage. This mastery may take the form of a competency in
gathering and interpreting labor market signals—a driving force behind strategic factor mar-
ket theory (Barney, 1986b; Makadok & Barney, 2001). For example, in the book Moneyball,
Michael Lewis (2004) describes how the Oakland Athletics used a different set of signals
than those of rivals and so were able to identify good baseball players that other teams ignored
and acquired those players at economic discounts.
Coping strategies for attraction dilemmas. Strategic HR scholars have devoted much
research to uncovering various selection policies and practices that reduce uncertainty and
improve fit in the hiring process (see Ployhart, 2006, for a recent review). However, our dis-
cussion has focused on the specific problems linked to firm-specificity, social complexity,
and causal ambiguity. These problems may not be present in all cases in equal measure. As
such, HR practices geared toward identifying those who can and will invest in specific human
capital may be important only in some contexts. These practices might include gaining labor
market intelligence through checking references or, perhaps, in-basket exercises to see if
applicants pick up subtleties as they respond to simulated problems. In other settings, the
problem may be finding people who fit into a team-based setting. Here, it may be more impor-
tant to develop an assessment center approach to identify team-based skills. Thus, the specific
bundle of HR policies may need to be just as idiosyncratic as the underlying human assets.
Beyond the application of idiosyncratic HR policies, we suggest two additional avenues
of research that especially highlight the micro-foundations of this attraction problem. First,
high-quality employees may be particularly concerned with the quality of coworkers, espe-
cially in knowledge-intensive environments where mentorship can have long-term career
impacts. Having current “stars” may help an organization attract future stars. This possibility
opens interesting avenues for human capital scholars where the economic value of hiring
stars is repeatedly questioned (Adler & Kwon, 2002; Groysberg & Lee, 2009)—since stars
can appropriate so much of their value, are they really worth the high market wages? If up-
and-coming stars are attracted by existing stars, then these up-and-coming stars may be
willing to make wage or other sacrifices in order to work with existing stars, just as employ-
ees may be willing to forego wages for other nonpecuniary job benefits (Cable & Turban,
2003; Stern, 2004).
Second, the interpersonal networks of current employees can provide excellent sources
of information about potential employees, as evidenced by recent increases in employee
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Paraphrase This Document

Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1435
referral programs. Firms appear to experience substantial hiring benefits, such as better
fit, higher employee quality, and lower subsequent turnover, by using employee referrals
(Fernandez, Castilla, & Moore, 2000). These benefits derive not from intraorganizational social
networks, or from any formal organizational ties, but rather from the informal and personal
social networks of the individual employees.
In this way, a focus on organization-level solutions to attraction dilemmas may lead to a
lack of emphasis on individual-level factors that may be critical in generating firm-level
heterogeneity in human capital. While heterogeneity among individuals may be the source
of substantial attraction and hiring dilemmas, individuals may also be part of the solution to
overcome these challenges. These examples of how individuals may help to mitigate hiring
dilemmas only scratch the surface. The strong focus on organization-level policies and rou-
tines has undoubtedly left many opportunities to integrate micro-foundations of attraction
and hiring into theories of human capital–based advantages.
Retaining Human Capital
Retention dilemmas from isolating mechanisms. The three isolating mechanisms also
engender challenges for retaining human capital. For example, a paradox arises from the fact
that firms often seek people who, once hired, will be adept at acquiring firm-specific knowl-
edge and routines. In this case, ironically, the best labor market signal of employee quality may
be whether individuals have gained specific skills at other firms (Morris, Alvarez, Barney, &
Molloy, 2010). The most observable indicator of employees’ firm-specific skills may be their
tenure at firms known to produce proprietary knowledge. The employees’ actual skills may not
be valuable outside of the focal firm, but the ability to acquire new firm-specific knowledge
may be quite valuable. The irony, then, is that knowledge that cannot be applied in other firms
may actually increase employees’ mobility, as other employers infer that such individuals will
be able to acquire new firm-specific knowledge. Accordingly, turnover may be more of a threat
for firm-specific human assets then is normally presumed in the literature (Becker, 1964).
Social complexity also may pose retention hazards. On one hand, it can have a strong
firm-specific component—as social complexity increases, employees need more sophisticated
mental mappings of who knows what and how things get done in the firm. Here, social com-
plexity may enhance retention if the social ties are valuable within the firm but not appli-
cable externally. Of course, as the discussion above suggests, the ability to form ties may be
in strong demand even if the actual ties are not.
On the other hand, some forms of social complexity may directly increase an individual’s
value in the labor market. Boundary spanners, for example, are embedded in complex social
networks that span both internal and external relationships. These boundary-spanning rela-
tionships may be quite valuable to rivals (Bartol, 1979; Kerr, von Glinow, & Schriesheim,
1977). Losing these boundary spanners, however, can be quite damaging because they are
critical for dynamic capabilities—that is, they often help the firm to incorporate external
knowledge and information. Accordingly, social complexity may directly or indirectly increase
the threat of employee turnover. Whether a given individual is at risk for turnover depends
on the nature of his or her social ties.
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
1436 Journal of Management / September 2011
Finally, causal ambiguity also can create a retention dilemma. It can increase talent reten-
tion because it is hard for rivals to identify knowledge that specific employees hold and the
relative value of that knowledge. At the same time, however, internal managers may not
know any more about employee skills than their competitors do. In knowledge-intensive
environments, it can be very difficult to identify who knows what and equally difficult to
identify how any one individual’s knowledge connects to performance outcomes. The prob-
lem for the manager, then, is identifying which employees to retain. Recent work by Oettl
(2010) shows that some stars may actually increase productivity more through helping others
than by producing themselves. As such, it may be especially hard to identify these “mavens”
in work environments where helping behaviors are not immediately clear to supervisors and/
or coworkers. For example, Grant Hill is the only person to have won the National Basketball
Association’s (NBA) sportsmanship award three times. While NBA players across the
league have voted repeatedly for Hill, his team-building behaviors may be hard for owners
to observe directly. If firms fail to retain these helpful stars, the firms may lose substantial
sources of economic productivity.
Potential coping strategies for retention dilemmas. One clear possibility for retaining
human capital is simply to pay people enough that they stay (Akerlof, 1984; Weiss, 1990)—
this distributes rent and thereby lowers observed profitability. Beyond this, there is a variety
of alternatives that may promote retention without allocating rent. Drawing from the turn-
over literature, we see that a person’s propensity to change jobs depends on perceptions of
the current job relative to alternatives (Shaw, Delery, Jenkins, & Gupta, 1998). Thus, firms
may decrease turnover by either (1) raising perceptions of the current job or (2) lowering
perceptions of alternatives. These perceptions can be influenced both by managing the non-
financial aspects of job satisfaction and by investing in firm-specific skills.
Firms can raise employee perceptions of the current job by managing the nonfinancial
facets of employee job satisfaction. Job satisfaction is featured prominently in the turnover
literature as a trigger to prompt search behavior (Hom, Caranikas-Walker, Prussia, & Griffeth,
1992; Lee, Mitchell, Wise, & Fireman, 1996). For example, the Job Descriptive Index mea-
sures five dimensions: (1) pay, (2) supervision, (3) coworkers, (4) promotion, and (5) the
work itself (Jung, Dalessio, & Johnson, 1986), and there is evidence that nonfinancial facets
can substitute for wages (Cable & Turban, 2003; Stern, 2004).
The four nonpecuniary dimensions of job satisfaction offer significant opportunities to
retain employees at potentially low cost. These dimensions can be elevated either through
systematic HR policies or through individual-level phenomena. First, firms can improve
satisfaction with supervision by training and selecting managers who provide learning
opportunities, promote employee participation, provide recognition, and promote fairness in
their decisions. Of course, we must also recognize that perceptions of the quality of supervi-
sion may be linked to specific high-profile leaders and role models as opposed to systematic
firm-level HR policies.
Second, satisfaction with coworkers can be increased by managing group demography
and social activities to create a team-based work environment (O’Reilly, Caldwell, & Barnett,
1989). As people develop strong relationships within the firm, they are less likely to leave
(Mitchell, Holtom, Lee, Sablynski, & Erez, 2001; Shaw, Duffy, Johnson, & Lockhart, 2005).
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1437
Similarly, individual-level processes may enhance satisfaction with coworkers. For example,
leaders may actively set work group norms that generate satisfaction with the team as a whole.
Third, firms can enhance satisfaction with promotion through HR policies that structure
desirable career paths such that assignments are offered as rewards. This is a consistently
important facet—especially among workers with substantial human capital (Rice, Gentile, &
McFarlin, 1991; Scarpello & Campbell, 1983). At the same time, individual managers may
play a role in framing work assignments as rewards or forms of recognition to employees.
Indeed, small changes in responsibilities may take on symbolic significance depending on
how they are presented.
The last dimension, the work itself, is particularly important to professionals who often
seek autonomy and input (Raelin, 1986)—something that may be inexpensive to provide. In
some cases, jobs are designed through active HR intervention. However, jobs often emerge
and are structured by line managers. As such, individual managers may be in a position to
generate intrinsically rewarding work settings.
In sum, since employees value nonfinancial dimensions of satisfaction, these facets can
substitute for wages while still enhancing retention. Indeed, some have studied the extent to
which attempts to motivate individuals extrinsically (wages, etc.) can crowd out natural
intrinsic motivation (Frey, 1993, 2002; Murdock, 2002). Since these intrinsic facets can be
quite valuable to employees, but inexpensive to maintain (once in place), they may serve as
important components of a sustainable advantage.
In addition to influencing perceptions of their current jobs, firms can affect employee
perceptions of alternative jobs. One way firms may affect employee perceptions of outside
options is by encouraging employees to become embedded in their organizations and com-
munities (Holtom, Mitchell, & Lee, 2006; Lee, Mitchell, Sablynski, Burton, & Holtom,
2004). The many links that employees form with other individuals and organizations in their
communities lead to idiosyncratic networks that are, by their very nature, very difficult to
re-create elsewhere. The more embedded employees become, the more likely they are to
believe that they cannot replace these networks should they choose to leave. In other words,
by helping employees to become socially embedded in their organizations and communities,
firms can change employee perceptions of their outside options. The strategic value of
embeddedness is not that employees derive value from their connections but that employees
derive more value from these connections than they think they can find elsewhere. While
embeddedness can emanate from unique HR policies, it may also emanate naturally from
interpersonal relationships or other aspects of organizational life not directly created or bestowed
by the firm and its managers.
Motivating Human Capital
Motivation dilemmas from isolating mechanisms. In addition to having the right human
capital, firms must deal with the complex problems associated with employee motivation.
Just having the right employees in place does not ensure that they will exert sufficient effort
toward essential work tasks. As with attraction and retention, each of the three isolating
mechanisms poses challenges in motivating employees.
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Secure Best Marks with AI Grader

Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
Document Page
1438 Journal of Management / September 2011
Firm-specificity, the first of the isolating mechanisms, is the focus of a classic human
capital motivation dilemma. Wang and Barney (2006) observe that while firm-specific
human capital may be critical for competitive advantage, employees may be unmotivated to
invest in such skills since they may effectively decrease their opportunities outside of the
firm. All else equal, employees may prefer not to undertake such investments.
Social complexity may pose a different sort of motivational challenge. Complex social
systems engender team production problems by which individual effort and contributions
are hard to observe (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972). This, in turn, makes it hard to rely on pow-
erful incentives and may lead to shirking, poor motivation, or even subversive behavior
(Ouchi, 1980). While these problems are addressed in agency theory (Jensen & Meckling,
1976), the motivation literature also documents reduced effort in some team settings (Kidwell
& Bennett, 1993). When individual contributions are intertwined, employees may be uncer-
tain about whether their efforts will impact outcomes (e.g., expectancy). In addition, the firm
cannot easily provide performance-based rewards (e.g., instrumentality). Finally, individuals
have distinct utility functions such that the value of rewards (valence) varies across people.
If valence, expectancy, and instrumentality are low, it will be hard to motivate employees
(Vroom, 1964).
Similarly, causal ambiguity paves the way for problems of moral hazard. People often
take credit for successes and assign external attributions for failures when it is difficult to
observe causality. Attribution theory refers to this as the “self-serving bias” (Miller & Ross,
1975). Therefore, it may be very hard for managers to recognize what behaviors and/or skills
ought to be rewarded. Since causality cannot be established, organizations may inadvertently
reward or punish employees for events that are beyond the employees’ control or influence
(Kerr, 1975, 1995).
Potential coping strategies for motivation dilemmas. Conventional solutions to the firm-
specific investment problem include offering higher wages to compensate employees for
firm-specific investments or providing contractual assurances of ex post compensation.
There may also be nonpecuniary or intrinsic rewards linked to human capital investments.
For example, socialization research suggests that individuals may actively choose to invest
in firm-specific human capital (Morrison, 1993). That is, people may experience positive util-
ity by matching a group’s norms, values, and culture (Gottschalg & Zollo, 2007; Morrison,
1993)—similar to what Foss (2011) calls a normative frame. Where organizational norms
support investments in firm-specific human capital, some individuals will choose to conform
with expectations. These norms may be reinforced both by HR policies to integrate new
hires and by specific individuals who espouse the norms.
The other motivation dilemmas arise around difficulties in identifying and measuring
individuals’ contributions. In this context, cultural norms may substitute for close monitor-
ing or powerful incentives (Ouchi, 1980). Some aspects of a corporate culture can be encour-
aged and maintained by HR policies and other organization-level routines (Lengnick-Hall &
Lengnick-Hall, 1988; Schein, 2004). For example, recruitment, selection, and recognition
systems can focus on those who espouse the firm’s core values. At the same time, high-profile
individuals who espouse those values may be invaluable and irreplaceable (Meindl, 1989;
Pettigrew, 1979). The idiosyncratic blend of critical individuals with organizational systems
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1439
may be a key to understanding why corporate culture holds so much promise as a source of
competitive advantage (Barney, 1986a).
Beyond this, individuals may play an important role in resolving the information asym-
metries that hinder effective reward systems. Performance appraisal data can be gathered
from a wide array of individuals who, in turn, have unique perspectives on each other. Such
360-degree feedback draws on individual variation in information and perspectives and may
therefore help firms craft effective incentives even in the context of social complexity or causal
ambiguity. Additionally, some firms are beginning to utilize social media to allow employ-
ees to nominate others for positive work as a way to better observe and reward performance.
Future Directions and Conclusion
While we agree that human capital provides a promising source of competitive advantage
in the resource-based theory of the firm, we add our voices to those who have called for
stronger micro-foundations for understanding resources and capabilities (Coff, 1997; Felin
& Hesterly, 2007; Foss, 2011; Teece, 2007). Here, we focus specifically on the context of
human capital–based advantages. Beyond our general call for research, we identify several
specific areas we believe will be particularly fruitful. A greater understanding of the micro-
foundations of human capital–based competitive advantage requires further integration of
micro theories of individual motivation and behavior with macro theories explaining firm-
level activities.
Table 1 summarizes our discussion of the role that individual-level differences play in
(1) creating management dilemmas that could hinder the emergence of a competitive advan-
tage and (2) discovering possible solutions to these challenges. This represents a rich set of
opportunities for further research needed to build a more robust theory of human capital–
based competitive advantages. In this way, we have contributed by highlighting how the
isolating mechanisms at the core of the resource-based view emanate from phenomena at the
individual level. These make human capital a promising source of competitive advantage, but
they also generate challenging management dilemmas that require idiosyncratic solutions.
These embedded dilemmas are probably not conducive to standardized organization-level
solutions. First, each firm is likely to experience idiosyncratic challenges depending on the
firm’s unique mix of people—there is no one size that fits all. Furthermore, the solutions require
the integration of firm-level systems with key individuals. This focus on idiosyncratic prob-
lems and cross-level solutions differs considerably from much of the extant literature.
In moving forward with this agenda, we see two especially fruitful avenues of inquiry.
First, the development of micro-foundations requires a better understanding of how firm-level
policies and procedures interact with individual-level phenomena. Here, we have focused on
how the idiosyncratic isolating mechanisms linked to human capital require similarly idio-
syncratic organizational policies and procedures. As such, we hope to see a move away from
studying standardized bundles of organizational best practices to identifying which practices
mitigate specific dilemmas arising from the idiosyncratic attributes of a given firm’s pool of
human capital. Some nascent research begins to explore whether firms with unique corporate
strategies also have superior performance. Likewise, there may be fruitful opportunities to
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
1440 Journal of Management / September 2011
explore whether firms with unique or idiosyncratic HR systems, as opposed to standard HR
systems, realize human capital–based advantages.
Second, while there has been a strong focus on such firm-level systems, there has been
less emphasis on the role of individuals. Here, we offered some examples of how individuals
may play central roles in addressing the dilemmas in attracting, retaining, and motivating
human capital. This is a central question of the emerging literature studying the impact of
stars on organizational outcomes (Groysberg & Lee, 2009). It is also quite apparent as we
observe stock prices that fluctuate with the health of key contributors such as Steve Jobs at
Apple Computer. Similarly, we hope to stimulate work that emphasizes the interaction of
key individuals with organizational systems. It seems likely that effective systems may be
cospecialized to create highly idiosyncratic capabilities composed of distinct structures,
systems, and individuals. One very interesting opportunity for future research may be to
explore how the reputations of current stars affect attraction of future stars and how rents are
divided accordingly. Are up-and-coming stars willing to accept lower wages in order to
work for current stars? If so, are current stars able to appropriate some of the value associated
with the productivity of up-and-coming stars?
In conclusion, we have argued that simply acquiring superior human capital is not enough,
despite conventional assumptions that superior human capital can lead to sustained com-
petitive advantage. We have reviewed the challenges associated with attracting, retaining,
and motivating human capital and explored how complex idiosyncratic cross-level solutions
are required to mitigate these challenges. There is much to be done, and the path will not be
easy given silo-like divisions among micro and macro scholars. Nevertheless, drilling down
in this way holds great promise in energizing the strategic human capital literature.
References
Abell, P., Felin, T., & Foss, N. 2008. Building micro-foundations for the routines, capabilities, and performance
links. Managerial and Decision Economics, 29: 489-502.
Adler, P., & Kwon, S. 2002. Social capital: Prospects for a new concept. Academy of Management Review, 27:
17-40.
Akerlof, G. 1970. The market for “lemons”: Qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 84: 488-500.
Akerlof, G. 1984. Gift exchange and efficiency-wage theory: Four views. American Economic Review, 74: 79-83.
Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic
Review, 62: 777-795.
Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. 1993. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, 14: 33-46.
Arthur, J. B. 1994. Effects of human resource systems on manufacturing performance and turnover. Academy of
Management Journal, 37: 670-687.
Ashenfelter, O. 1978. Estimating the effect of training programs on earnings. Review of Economics and Statistics,
60(1): 47-57.
Ashenfelter, O., & Krueger, A. 1994. Estimates of the economic return to schooling from a new sample of twins.
American Economic Review, 84: 1157-1173.
Barney, J. 1986a. Organizational culture: Can it be a source of sustained competitive advantage? Academy of
Management Review, 11: 656-665.
Barney, J. 1986b. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management Science, 32:
1231-1241.
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Paraphrase This Document

Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1441
Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99-120.
Bartol, K. M. 1979. Professionalism as a predictor of organizational commitment, role stress, and turnover: A
multidimensional approach. Academy of Management Journal, 22: 815-821.
Becker, B., & Huselid, M. 2006. Strategic human resources management: Where do we go from here? Journal of
Management, 32: 898-925.
Becker, G. 1964. Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Borgatti, S. P., & Cross, R. 2003. A relational view of information seeking and learning in social networks.
Management Science, 49: 432-445.
Cable, D., & Turban, D. 2003. The value of organizational reputation in the recruitment context: A brand-equity
perspective. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 33: 2244-2266.
Chadwick, C., & Dabu, A. 2009. Human resource management, and the competitive advantage of firms: Toward a
more comprehensive model of causal linkages. Organization Science, 20: 253–272.
Coff, R. 1997. Human assets and management dilemmas: Coping with hazards on the road to resource-based the-
ory. Academy of Management Review, 22: 374-402.
Delfgaauw, J., & Dur, R. 2007. Signaling and screening of workers’ motivation. Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 62: 605-624.
Felin, T., & Hesterly, W. 2007. The knowledge-based view, nested heterogeneity, and new value creation: Philosophical
considerations on the locus of knowledge. Academy of Management Review, 32: 195-218.
Fernandez, R. M., Castilla, E. J., & Moore, P. 2000. Social capital at work: Networks and employment at a phone
center. American Journal of Sociology, 105: 1288-1356.
Foss, N. J. 2011. Why micro-foundations for resource-based theory are needed and what they may look like.
Journal of Management. Prepublished December 10, 2010. DOI:10.1177/0149206310390218.
Frey, B. S. 1993. Motivation as a limit to pricing. Journal of Economic Psychology, 14: 635-664.
Frey, B. S. 2002. Creativity, government and the arts. De Economist, 150: 363-376.
Gottschalg, O., & Zollo, M. 2007. Interest alignment and competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review,
32: 418-437.
Griliches, Z. 1977. Estimating the returns to schooling: Some econometric problems. Econometrica, 45: 1-22.
Groysberg, B., & Lee, L. E. 2009. Hiring stars and their colleagues: Exploration and exploitation in professional
service firms. Organization Science, 20: 740-758.
Hall, R. 1993. A framework linking intangible resources and capabilities to sustainable competitive advantage.
Strategic Management Journal, 14: 607-618.
Hatch, N. W., & Dyer, J. H. 2004. Human capital and learning as a source of sustainable competitive advantage.
Strategic Management Journal, 25: 1155-1178.
Holtom, B., Mitchell, T., & Lee, T. 2006. Increasing human and social capital by applying job embeddedness
theory. Organizational Dynamics, 35: 316-331.
Hom, P. W., Caranikas-Walker, F., Prussia, G. E., & Griffeth, R. W. 1992. A meta-analytical structural equations
analysis of a model of employee turnover. Journal of Applied Psychology, 77: 890-890.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and capital structure.
Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360.
Jung, K., Dalessio, A., & Johnson, S. 1986. Stability of the factor structure of the job descriptive index. Academy
of Management Journal, 29: 609-616.
Kerr, S. 1975. On the folly of rewarding A, while hoping for B. Academy of Management Journal, 18: 769-783.
Kerr, S. 1995. On the folly of rewarding A while hoping for B. Academy of Management Executive, 9: 7-14.
Kerr, S., von Glinow, M. A., & Schriesheim, J. 1977. Issues in the study of professionals in organizations: The case
of scientists and engineers. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 18: 329-345.
Kidwell, R. E., & Bennett, N. 1993. Employee propensity to withhold effort: A conceptual model to intersect three
avenues of research. Academy of Management Review, 18: 429-456.
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., & Alchian, A. A. 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive
contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21: 297-326.
Kor, Y. Y., & Leblebici, H. 2005. How do interdependencies among human-capital deployment, development, and
diversification strategies affect firms’ financial performance? Strategic Management Journal, 26: 967-985.
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
1442 Journal of Management / September 2011
Lado, A., & Wilson, M. 1994. Human resource systems and sustained competitive advantage: A competency-based
perspective. Academy of Management Review, 19: 699-727.
Lazear, E. P. 2009. Firm-specific human capital: A skill-weights approach. Journal of Political Economy, 117:
914-940.
Lee, T. W., Mitchell, T. R., Sablynski, C. J., Burton, J. P., & Holtom, B. C. 2004. The effects of job embeddedness
on organizational citizenship, job performance, volitional absences, and voluntary turnover. Academy of
Management Journal, 47: 711-722.
Lee, T. W., Mitchell, T. R., Wise, L., & Fireman, S. 1996. An unfolding model of voluntary turnover. Academy of
Management Journal, 39: 5-36.
Lengnick-Hall, C. A., & Lengnick-Hall, M. L. 1988. Strategic human resources management: A review of the lit-
erature and a proposed typology. Academy of Management Review, 13: 454-470.
Lewis, M. M. 2004. Moneyball: The art of winning an unfair game. New York: Norton.
Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. 1982. Uncertain imitability: An analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency
under competition. Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 418-438.
Makadok, R., & Barney, J. 2001. Strategic factor market intelligence: An application of information economics to
strategy formulation and competitor intelligence. Management Science, 47: 1621-1639.
Meindl, J. R. 1989. Managing to be fair: An exploration of values, motives, and leadership. Administrative Science
Quarterly, 34: 252-276.
Miller, D. T., & Ross, M. 1975. Self-serving biases in the attribution of causality: Fact or fiction? Psychological
Bulletin, 82: 213-225.
Mitchell, T., Holtom, B., Lee, T., Sablynski, C., & Erez, M. 2001. Why people stay: Using job embeddedness to
predict voluntary turnover. Academy of Management Journal, 44: 1102-1122.
Morris, S., Alvarez, S., Barney, J., & Molloy, J. 2010. Employee investments in firm-specific human capital and
firm level competitive advantage. Working manuscript.
Morrison, E. W. 1993. Longitudinal study of the effects of information seeking on newcomer socialization. Journal
of Applied Psychology, 78: 173-173.
Murdock, K. 2002. Intrinsic motivation and optimal incentive contracts. Rand Journal of Economics, 33: 650-671.
Oettl, A. 2010. Productivity and helpfulness: Implications of a new taxonomy for star scientists. Working manuscript.
O’Reilly, C., III, Caldwell, D., & Barnett, W. P. 1989. Work group demography, social integration, and turnover.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 34: 21-37.
O’Reilly, C., III, Chatman, J., & Caldwell, D. 1991. People and organizational culture: A profile comparison
approach to assessing person–organization fit. Academy of Management Journal, 34: 487-516.
Ouchi. 1980. Markets, bureaucracies, and clans. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 129-141.
Peteraf, M., & Barney, J. 2003. Unraveling the resource-based tangle. Managerial and Decision Economics, 24:
309-323.
Pettigrew, A. M. 1979. On studying organizational cultures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 24: 570-581.
Ployhart, R. E. 2006. Staffing in the 21st century: New challenges and strategic opportunities. Journal of Management,
32: 868-897.
Ployhart, R. E., & Moliterno, T. P. 2011. Emergence of the human capital resource: A multilevel model. Academy
of Management Review, 36: 127-150.
Raelin, J. A. 1986. The clash of cultures: Managers and professionals. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Reed, R., & DeFillippi, R. J. 1990. Casual ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage.
Academy of Management Review, 15: 88-102.
Rice, R., Gentile, D., & McFarlin, D. 1991. Facet importance and job satisfaction. Journal of Applied Psychology,
76: 31-39.
Scarpello, V., & Campbell, J. P. 1983. Job satisfaction: Are all the parts there? Personnel Psychology, 36: 577-600.
Schein, E. H. 2004. Organizational culture and leadership. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Schneider, B. 1987. The people make the place. Personnel Psychology, 40: 437-453.
Shaw, J. D., Delery, J. E., Jenkins, G. D., Jr., & Gupta, N. 1998. An organization-level analysis of voluntary and
involuntary turnover. Academy of Management Journal, 41: 511-525.
Shaw, J., Duffy, M. K., Johnson, J. L., & Lockhart, D. E. 2005. Turnover, social capital losses, and performance.
Academy of Management Journal, 48: 594-96. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/20159681.
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
Document Page
Coff, Kryscynski / Human Capital–Based Advantages 1443
Spence, M. 1973. Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87: 355-374.
Stern, S. 2004. Do scientists pay to be scientists? Management Science, 50: 835-853.
Teece, D. 2007. Explicating dynamic capabilities: The nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise
performance. Strategic Management Journal, 28: 1319-1350.
Trank, C., Rynes, S., & Bretz, R. 2002. Attracting applicants in the war for talent: Differences in work preferences
among high achievers. Journal of Business and Psychology, 16: 331-345.
Vroom, V. H. 1964. Work and motivation. New York: Wiley.
Wang, H., & Barney, J. 2006. Employee incentives to make firm-specific investments: Implications for resource-
based theories of corporate diversification. Academy of Management Review, 31: 466-476.
Weiss, A. 1990. Efficiency wages: Models of unemployment, layoffs, and wage dispersion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies, analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.
at UNIV TORONTO on November 23, 2014jom.sagepub.comDownloaded from
1 out of 16
circle_padding
hide_on_mobile
zoom_out_icon
[object Object]

Your All-in-One AI-Powered Toolkit for Academic Success.

Available 24*7 on WhatsApp / Email

[object Object]