This essay discusses the concept of efficient market structure and compares and contrasts the perfectly competitive model with monopoly in the market place. It covers topics such as allocative efficiency, productive efficiency, technological efficiency, externalities, price discrimination, and innovation.
Contribute Materials
Your contribution can guide someone’s learning journey. Share your
documents today.
Running head: MICROECONOMICS 101 Microeconomics 101: Economics Essay Name of the Student: Name of the University: Authors Note:
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
MICROECONOMICS 101 What is meant by an efficient market structure and compare and contrast perfectly competitive model with monopoly in the market place? Perfect competition is a market structure dominated by many firms. There is a large number of buyers and sellers, free entry and exit of firms, homogeneous product that have perfect mobility of factors of production and perfect knowledge (Gans, King & Mankiw, 2014). Profit maximization is the goal of the producer where the firm produces the output at Q1 with equilibrium price at Pe such that AR=MR, also the demand and supply are in line with the price equilibrium (Pe). The efficiency quotient lies because at Q1 diseconomies is the same as economies of scale (P=AR=MR=AC=MC) and there is no excess capacity and there is perfect allocation of resources with normal profits in long run (Carlton & Perloff, 2015) Figure 1: Efficient market structure Source: (Ten Kate, 2016) The economic efficiency quotient can be measured based on the three primary parameters of efficiency that is, allocative efficiency, productive efficiency and technological efficiency (Färe, Grosskopf & Lovell, 2013).
MICROECONOMICS 101 For allocative efficiency, the market structure should fulfil two criteria’s one is Marginal social benefit is equal to marginal social cost (MSB = MSC) and price and marginal cost should be equal (P = MC) (Waldman & Jensen, 2016). Then for productive efficiency, the resources should be optimally utilized which can be well depicted by production possibility curve (PPC) and lastly technological efficiency is achieved when each firm in the industry produce at the minimum of Average Total Cost (ATC) Curve (Becker, 2017). When comparing the market structure for perfectly competitive market and monopoly, the economic efficiency can be achieved if all the three efficiencies are fulfilled. Allocative efficiency is where goods are distributed among consumer preferences such that in the above diagram of perfect competition, in the firm part, at Q1 quantity demanded where, Pe=MC. In the industry part, its enclosed by demand and supply curve with Pe price and Q1 quantity demanded. The point of perfect allocation will be achieved where the consumer surplus will be equal to producer surplus. However, in monopolies, it is said to be allocatively inefficient because the price is above the marginal cost (Scitovsky, 2013). On the contrary, in perfectly competitive market, the firm produces where marginal social benefit (MSB) is equal to marginal social cost (MSC), but as the monopoly curve does not has a supply curve, the MSB = MSC is not true for monopoly. In addition, monopolies have market power which diminishes the consumer surplus and makes them earn supernormal profits as shown in figure 2.
MICROECONOMICS 101 Figure 2: Allocative inefficiency in Monopoly Source: (Scitovsky, 2013) Mathematically, allocative efficiency can even be studied using Pareto Optimality where by describing specific levels of consumptions for a consumer can be determined with specific input with each producers output level. Although, pareto optimality is the basis for welfare economics but it cannot be used to increase the utility of an individual without decreasing the utility of others. Nevertheless, if individually in perfectly competitive market, the rate of consumer substitution (RCS) is analysed for a pair of goods on a price ratio, it can be given as: RCSjk= pj/ pk(where j and k are commodities/ factors) However, when the firms are profit maximisers then, RPTjk(Rate of product transformation) = pj/ pk MPjk(Marginal Product) = pj/ pk(Both j and k refers to factors) RPTjk= RCSjk.(Hence, as per the condition, pareto optimality is seen in perfectly competitive market) (Henderson & Quandt, 2013). On the contrary, if prices were not equal to Marginal Cost then prices are proportional to MC. Equating in terms of pi/ pj= (1/θ)*MPij; pi/ pk= (1/θ)*MPik(j and k commodities and i is factor). Therefore, perfect competition characterizes to be a welfare ideal for requirements of Pareto optimality if the assumptions are not violated. It cannot be said the same for imperfect competition or monopoly because in commodity market or factor market it does not satisfy the optimal resource allocation, MP = r/p = RCS
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
MICROECONOMICS 101 p = r/ MP = MC p * MP = r, this equation does not satisfy for one or more sellers making it pareto nonoptimal for the monopoly market structure (Henderson & Quandt, 2013). On the other hand, productive efficiency is the optimal combination of the goods produced with the inputs to produce maximum output for the minimum cost. Productive efficiency can be explained with production possibility frontier (PPC) where loss of output on one good leads to gain of output of other (Stryk, 2013). Figure 3: Production Possibility Curve Source:(Pindyck & Rubinfeld, 2015) Diagrammatically in figure 3, it can be explained that point A is productively efficient whereas B and C are productively inefficient because more of goods and services can be utilizedwithno opportunitycost.Based ontheanalysisof marketstructure,perfect competition is productively efficient where AC is at its minimum whereas the same cannot be said for monopoly (Waldman & Jensen, 2016). Thirdly, technological efficiency can be stated in two ways whether with given the output produced, the costs of production are minimized or whether given the costs of production, the output is maximized. In perfectly competitive market, the firms are producing
MICROECONOMICS 101 on their cost curves and all the firms wishes to minimize the costs so that the profits are not maximised. In addition, the perfectly competitive market gives zero profit in the long run. However, profit in the industry are producing at the minimum point on ATC to not be driven out of business in long run by its efficiently placed competitors (Pindyck & Rubinfeld, 2015). Whereas in a monopoly, the firms are notproducing on their cost curves because a monopoly operates on minimizing costs and increasing profits and the industry is even not producing on the minimum point on the cost curve ATC because the Pm >AC. Hence, its producing too little at a high price (Zeuthen, 2018). According to the comparisons between perfectly competitive market and monopoly, the perfectly competitive market is efficient because they have the least market power and yield the efficient outcome whereas the same cannot be said for monopoly. Monopoly is a “Price Maker” and deals with one commodity whereas perfectly competitive market is a “Price Taker” and deals with homogeneous products (Waldman & Jensen, 2016). In the actual world perfect competition is a myth but there is prevalence of perfect competition in agriculture and local farm products where there are many fruits and vegetables sold at the same price with no competition at all. However, there are certain exceptions to the analysis that needs to be examined because there are times when the perfectly competitive market cannot be as efficient as understood and monopoly cannot be inefficient as presumed (Kirzner, 2015). There are exception of both types that can be described additional to the given analysis. When in terms of contestable markets, it has single or less firms which produce a product with no close substitutes and there is no competition from other firms (Mahoney & Weyl, 2017). Also, it keeps the costs under control with minimum wastage of the resources and even from further exploitation of the consumers by setting high prices and gaining from its profit margins. As a result, there are no barriers to entry, that is, entry and exit are cost free and exhibits level of
MICROECONOMICS 101 economic efficiency in long run (Page, 2013). Hence, amonopolywill not raise its price to its monopoly price because there is no threat for the competition that exists. Externalities, can be other point, where the exchange happening between buyer and seller can be affected to the third party whether negatively or positively. In regards to positive externality, the third party has gained from the exchange because there is no demand curve but only private advantage of the product (Okun, 2015). In this case, MSB exceeds the demand curve. In contrast to this, negative externality is when the third party has suffered loss from the exchange because the cost is not equal to the supply curve as it only includes the costs of production of the product to the sellers making marginal social cost higher than supply curve. When analysed from the perspective of allocative efficiency inperfectly competitive market, there will be misallocation of resources such that there will be less output at a low price (positive externality) or more output at a low price (negative externality) (Pindyck & Rubinfeld, 2015). A monopolist can charge different price from different customers. The maximum price which a consumer is willing to pay is knows as Reservation Price. This happens because cost of production differs. For example, the people who go to see a movie in a matinee hall will be charged a lower price than the people who go to see a movie in a multiplex. This helps in increasing the efficiencies ofmonopolyand is done on the basis of people who wish to give away their consumer surplus (Waldman & Jensen, 2016). Alternatively, natural monopoly termed as monopoly of a firm can price the entire output of the market at a cost lower than other several firms. This kind of monopoly arises due to strong economies of scale. A single large firm always has lower average costs than do smaller firms, the larger firm will always be able to drive out smaller, less cost-effective, competitors (Hayek, 2016). A monopolized industry will be the natural result of this process.
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
MICROECONOMICS 101 Economies of scope arise in terms of a single situation when one good is profitable and other is not and both can be produced at lower average cost than the other small competitors (becker, 2013). The scope of production, in contrast to the scale of production, prefers not to increasing the quantity produced but to increasing the number of products produced by the firm. For example, railways, hospitals, etc. Price discrimination is other factor where a different price is charged to a different customer even though the cost of production remains the same (Pigou, 2017). This is one exception that supports monopoly’s efficiency based on three requirements – one is that the firm should have some market power not importantly a monopolist but not even a perfectly competitive firms; second firms must be able to separate the market in two groups at least to identify the group who will pay higher or lower and third is reselling of the products are important. However, if perfect price discrimination is considered then a minimum of two groups have been made upon knowledge. In this case, when discriminating price, marginal revenue will be equal to demand because the price charged to first customer would be the same irrespectiveof theprice tothe followingcustomers(Weyl&Fabinger, 2013). Diagrammatically in figure 4, P = MR and P = MC creating allocative efficient output. Figure 4: Perfect Price Discrimination
MICROECONOMICS 101 Source: (Pigou, 2017) If innovation has to take place, technology will change. As a result inperfectly competitive market, if technology changes, profit will rise and entry will occur and even if it tries to gain it zero profit situation, there will be no incentive to innovate whereas in monopolyif innovation happens, price rises with barriers to entry, price rises and there will be incentive to innovate (Waldman & Jensen, 2016). From all these points, a conclusion can be derived that a perfectly competitive market is efficient in terms of allocative and technological efficiency with least market power but on the other hand, keeping all the exceptions in mind with the constraint of barriers to entry a monopoly can achieve technological efficiency. Although, when it comes to productive efficiency, a perfectly competitive market do not use its resources to the fullest while giving maximum services whereas in monopoly it can happen in terms of innovation and price discrimination. One can see the prevalence of a monopoly through railways in railroad transportation, government control of nuclear power, state electricity board monopoly over generation and distribution of electricity in all states.
MICROECONOMICS 101 References Becker, G. S. (2017).Economic theory. New York: Routledge. Carlton, D. W., & Perloff, J. M. (2015).Modern industrial organization. Massachusetts: Pearson Higher Ed. Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., & Lovell, C. K. (2013).The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol. 6). New York: Springer Science & Business Media. Gans, J., King, S., & Mankiw, N. (2014). Principles of Microeconomics. Australia: Cengage Learning. Hayek, F. A. (2016). The meaning of competition.Econ Journal Watch, 13(2), 360-373. Henderson, J. M., & Quandt, R. E. (2013).Microeconomic theory: A mathematical approach. New York: McGraw-Hill Kirzner, I. M. (2015).Competition and entrepreneurship. London: University of Chicago press. Mahoney, N., & Weyl, E. G. (2017). Imperfect competition in selection markets.Review of Economics and Statistics, 99(4), 637-651. Okun, A. M. (2015).Equality and efficiency: The big tradeoff. Washington: Brookings Institution Press. Page, T. (2013).Conservation and economic efficiency: an approach to materials policy. New York: RFF Press. Pigou, A. (2017).The economics of welfare. London: Routledge. Pindyck, R., & Rubinfeld, D. (2015).Microeconomics, Global Edition (8th ed). Essex: Pearson Education Limited.
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
MICROECONOMICS 101 Scitovsky, T. (2013).Welfare & Competition. New York: Routledge. Stryk, D. (2013).International Economics Study Guide and Workbook. London: Routledge. Ten Kate, A. (2016). Economic Efficiency as the Ultimate Goal of Competition Policy. AvailableatSSRN:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2740523or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2740523 Waldman, D., & Jensen, E. (2016).Industrial organization: theory and practice. New York: Routledge. Weyl, E. G., & Fabinger, M. (2013). Pass-through as an economic tool: Principles of incidence under imperfect competition.Journal of Political Economy, 121(3), 528- 583. Zeuthen, F. (2018).Problems of monopoly and economic warfare. London: Routledge.