The Gravity Model and Trade Efficiency: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis of Potential Trade
VerifiedAdded on 2023/06/15
|32
|8745
|393
AI Summary
This paper assesses potential trade against a maximum level of trade feasible for the group of 10 new member states (NMS) using a stochastic frontier approach to estimating the gravity equation. The findings indicate a high degree of East West trade integration close to two thirds of frontier estimates, suggesting a low degree of trade resistances.
Contribute Materials
Your contribution can guide someone’s learning journey. Share your
documents today.
DISCUSSION PAPERS
IN
ECONOMICS
No. 2013/4 ISSN 1478-9396
THE GRAVITY MODEL AND TRADE
EFFICIENCY: A STOCHASTIC FRONTIER
ANALYSIS OF POTENTIAL TRADE
GEETHA RAVISHANKAR
IN
ECONOMICS
No. 2013/4 ISSN 1478-9396
THE GRAVITY MODEL AND TRADE
EFFICIENCY: A STOCHASTIC FRONTIER
ANALYSIS OF POTENTIAL TRADE
GEETHA RAVISHANKAR
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS
The economic research undertaken at Nottingham Trent University
covers various fields of economics. But, a large part of it was grouped
into two categories, Applied Economics and Policy and Political
Economy.
This paper is part of the new series, Discussion Papers in
Economics.
Earlier papers in all series can be found at:
http://www.ntu.ac.uk/research/research_at_ntu/academic_schools/nbs
/working_papers.html
Enquiries concerning this or any of our other Discussion Papers should
be addressed to the Editors:
Dr. Marie Stack, Email: marie.stack@ntu.ac.uk
Dr. Dan Wheatley, Email: daniel.wheatley2@ntu.ac.uk
Division of Economics
Nottingham Trent University
Burton Street, Nottingham, NG1 4BU
UNITED KINGDOM.
The economic research undertaken at Nottingham Trent University
covers various fields of economics. But, a large part of it was grouped
into two categories, Applied Economics and Policy and Political
Economy.
This paper is part of the new series, Discussion Papers in
Economics.
Earlier papers in all series can be found at:
http://www.ntu.ac.uk/research/research_at_ntu/academic_schools/nbs
/working_papers.html
Enquiries concerning this or any of our other Discussion Papers should
be addressed to the Editors:
Dr. Marie Stack, Email: marie.stack@ntu.ac.uk
Dr. Dan Wheatley, Email: daniel.wheatley2@ntu.ac.uk
Division of Economics
Nottingham Trent University
Burton Street, Nottingham, NG1 4BU
UNITED KINGDOM.
The Gravity Model and Trade Efficiency:
A Stochastic Frontier Analysis of Potential Trade
ABSTRACT
The opening up process of the eastern European countries is characterised by an
increasing degree of trade integration with their Western neigbouring countries.
Typically, the degree of East West trade integration is assessed by comparing actual trade
volumes with potential trade volumes projected from the gravity model parameters
estimated for a group of countries that best represent normal trade relations. This
approach, however, does not compare trade levels against a maximum level of trade
feasible for the group of eastern European countries. This paper by using a stochastic
frontier specification of the gravity model is able to identify the efficiency of trade
integration relative to maximum potential levels. The findings, based on a panel data set
of bilateral exports from 17 Western European countries to the 10 new member states
over the 1994 2007 period, indicate a high degree of East West trade integration close to
two thirds of frontier estimates, suggesting a low degree of trade resistances.
JEL Classification: C33, F14, F15
Keywords: Gravity model, Potential trade, Efficiency scores
A Stochastic Frontier Analysis of Potential Trade
ABSTRACT
The opening up process of the eastern European countries is characterised by an
increasing degree of trade integration with their Western neigbouring countries.
Typically, the degree of East West trade integration is assessed by comparing actual trade
volumes with potential trade volumes projected from the gravity model parameters
estimated for a group of countries that best represent normal trade relations. This
approach, however, does not compare trade levels against a maximum level of trade
feasible for the group of eastern European countries. This paper by using a stochastic
frontier specification of the gravity model is able to identify the efficiency of trade
integration relative to maximum potential levels. The findings, based on a panel data set
of bilateral exports from 17 Western European countries to the 10 new member states
over the 1994 2007 period, indicate a high degree of East West trade integration close to
two thirds of frontier estimates, suggesting a low degree of trade resistances.
JEL Classification: C33, F14, F15
Keywords: Gravity model, Potential trade, Efficiency scores
1. INTRODUCTION
Not unlike the drive to increase trade between the established European Union (EU)
member countries as part of a customs union, the opening up process of the eastern
European countries began with trade integration. Strong bilateral trade links were formed
in advance of formal EU entry. After the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance
(CMEA) system1 was dissolved in the early 1990s, a new era of trade expansion was
ushered in, culminating in the Western European countries becoming the main trading
partners for the excommunist countries.
Figure 1 plots each new EU member country’s share of world trade (exports plus
imports) with the Western European countries. By 1994, Western Europe had already
become important trading partners for the group of ten, implying an almost immediate
release of economic ties from the former Soviet Union. Trailing behind its counterparts,
Lithuania was initially the slowest to open up its trade links, but increased its trade shares
by 1.5 times within a decade. Slovakia experienced an even more dramatic reorientation
of trade westwards, rising by two thirds to its peak levels in 2003. Conducting about half
of its trade with the Western countries in 1993, the trade shares for Bulgaria and Romania
depict an almost parallel trend, but with the latter maintaining a ten per cent lead over the
former. Much like Bulgaria’s path, the trade shares for Estonia and Latvia have ended up
like they started albeit with some variation in between. The trade shares for the top four
ranking countries, namely the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia remain
Not unlike the drive to increase trade between the established European Union (EU)
member countries as part of a customs union, the opening up process of the eastern
European countries began with trade integration. Strong bilateral trade links were formed
in advance of formal EU entry. After the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance
(CMEA) system1 was dissolved in the early 1990s, a new era of trade expansion was
ushered in, culminating in the Western European countries becoming the main trading
partners for the excommunist countries.
Figure 1 plots each new EU member country’s share of world trade (exports plus
imports) with the Western European countries. By 1994, Western Europe had already
become important trading partners for the group of ten, implying an almost immediate
release of economic ties from the former Soviet Union. Trailing behind its counterparts,
Lithuania was initially the slowest to open up its trade links, but increased its trade shares
by 1.5 times within a decade. Slovakia experienced an even more dramatic reorientation
of trade westwards, rising by two thirds to its peak levels in 2003. Conducting about half
of its trade with the Western countries in 1993, the trade shares for Bulgaria and Romania
depict an almost parallel trend, but with the latter maintaining a ten per cent lead over the
former. Much like Bulgaria’s path, the trade shares for Estonia and Latvia have ended up
like they started albeit with some variation in between. The trade shares for the top four
ranking countries, namely the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia remain
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
A two stage gravity approach to projecting East West trade volumes is the usual
route to assessing bilateral trade performance. In the first stage, the gravity model of trade
is estimated for a group of countries that best represent normal trade relations. In its basic
form, the standard gravity equation explains bilateral trade as a function of the economic
size of two countries and the distance between them (Tinbergen 1962; Pöyhönen 1963).
The augmented version additionally includes income per head for both countries and
other trade impeding or trade stimulating factors (Bergstrand 1989).
In the second stage, the gravity model parameters that fit a model of a normal
country’s geographic trade patterns are used to project the expected trade flows in an East
West direction. The trade flows predicted by the model can then be compared with actual
trade flows to assess the likelihood for future expansion or depletion of trade links
between a pair of countries. Whereas a value in excess of unity suggests remaining
potential for trade growth, a value of less than unity suggests trade potential is already
exhausted. In this way, the potential to actual trade ratios are informative as to the degree
of East West trade integration under normal conditions.
The two stage approach to trade projections pervades the empirical literature (see,
for example, Baldwin 1994; Gros and Gonciarz 1996; Stack and Pentecost 2010). In
assuming full economic liberalisation, these studies define East West potential trade in
terms of the sample average, usually the Western European countries. In other words, the
mean effects of trade determinants are estimated, implying potential trade is assessed
route to assessing bilateral trade performance. In the first stage, the gravity model of trade
is estimated for a group of countries that best represent normal trade relations. In its basic
form, the standard gravity equation explains bilateral trade as a function of the economic
size of two countries and the distance between them (Tinbergen 1962; Pöyhönen 1963).
The augmented version additionally includes income per head for both countries and
other trade impeding or trade stimulating factors (Bergstrand 1989).
In the second stage, the gravity model parameters that fit a model of a normal
country’s geographic trade patterns are used to project the expected trade flows in an East
West direction. The trade flows predicted by the model can then be compared with actual
trade flows to assess the likelihood for future expansion or depletion of trade links
between a pair of countries. Whereas a value in excess of unity suggests remaining
potential for trade growth, a value of less than unity suggests trade potential is already
exhausted. In this way, the potential to actual trade ratios are informative as to the degree
of East West trade integration under normal conditions.
The two stage approach to trade projections pervades the empirical literature (see,
for example, Baldwin 1994; Gros and Gonciarz 1996; Stack and Pentecost 2010). In
assuming full economic liberalisation, these studies define East West potential trade in
terms of the sample average, usually the Western European countries. In other words, the
mean effects of trade determinants are estimated, implying potential trade is assessed
trade performance against a maximum possible level of potential trade defined by a
stochastic frontier.
This paper assesses potential trade against a maximum level of trade feasible for
the group of 10 new member states (NMS) using a stochastic frontier approach to
estimating the gravity equation. Specifically, a trade frontier representing the maximum
possible level of bilateral trade is constructed for a panel of exports from 17 Western
European countries to the new EU member countries over the 1994 2007 period, covering
the transformation phase from communism to EU accession. The efficiency scores are
then generated from this frontier specification of the gravity model. If two countries
achieve an efficient level of trade, they will operate on the trade frontier and will realise
their maximum trade potential otherwise deviations of observed trade levels from the
trade frontier indicate inefficient levels of trade, implying scope for further trade
expansion. The frontier specification of the gravity model is similar in approach to that
used by Drysdale et al. (2000) who consider China’s trade efficiency, Kalirajan and
Singh (2008) who conduct a comparative analysis of export potential for China and India
and Armstrong et al. (2008) who compare trade performance in East Asia and South
Asia.
The efficiency scores suggest a high degree of East West trade integration, with
each new member state achieving on average two thirds of frontier estimates over the
1994 2007 period. The high efficiency scores indicate a low degree of trade resistances.
stochastic frontier.
This paper assesses potential trade against a maximum level of trade feasible for
the group of 10 new member states (NMS) using a stochastic frontier approach to
estimating the gravity equation. Specifically, a trade frontier representing the maximum
possible level of bilateral trade is constructed for a panel of exports from 17 Western
European countries to the new EU member countries over the 1994 2007 period, covering
the transformation phase from communism to EU accession. The efficiency scores are
then generated from this frontier specification of the gravity model. If two countries
achieve an efficient level of trade, they will operate on the trade frontier and will realise
their maximum trade potential otherwise deviations of observed trade levels from the
trade frontier indicate inefficient levels of trade, implying scope for further trade
expansion. The frontier specification of the gravity model is similar in approach to that
used by Drysdale et al. (2000) who consider China’s trade efficiency, Kalirajan and
Singh (2008) who conduct a comparative analysis of export potential for China and India
and Armstrong et al. (2008) who compare trade performance in East Asia and South
Asia.
The efficiency scores suggest a high degree of East West trade integration, with
each new member state achieving on average two thirds of frontier estimates over the
1994 2007 period. The high efficiency scores indicate a low degree of trade resistances.
The layout of this paper is as follows. Section 2 sets out the gravity model
specification, distinguishing between the conventional gravity equation and the stochastic
frontier gravity equation. The data sources and the expected coefficient signs are also
given in this section. The results in Section 3 are split between the gravity model
coefficient estimates and the efficiency scores of potential trade. Section 4 concludes.
2. MODEL SPECIFICATION AND DATA
2.1 The Gravity Equation
The gravity model specification for calculating trade volumes (Baldwin 1994; Gros and
Gonciarz 1996; Nilsson 2000) is typically of the following form:
t
j
t
iij
t
j
t
i
t
ij GDPPCGDPPCDISTGDPGDPTRADE 543210
t
ij
K
k
t
ijk
G
g
ijg XZ 11
(1)
where t
ijTRADE are the bilateral trade flows between countries i and j over a given
time period t ; t
iGDP and t
jGDP denote the economic size of both countries; ijDIST is
the geographic distance between their economic centres; and t
iGDPPC and t
jGDPPC are
the respective countries’ per capita income levels capturing factor endowments in the
exporting country and consumption patterns in the importing country. Equation (1) also
includes a vector of time invariant explanatory variables, ijZ ; a vector of time varying
specification, distinguishing between the conventional gravity equation and the stochastic
frontier gravity equation. The data sources and the expected coefficient signs are also
given in this section. The results in Section 3 are split between the gravity model
coefficient estimates and the efficiency scores of potential trade. Section 4 concludes.
2. MODEL SPECIFICATION AND DATA
2.1 The Gravity Equation
The gravity model specification for calculating trade volumes (Baldwin 1994; Gros and
Gonciarz 1996; Nilsson 2000) is typically of the following form:
t
j
t
iij
t
j
t
i
t
ij GDPPCGDPPCDISTGDPGDPTRADE 543210
t
ij
K
k
t
ijk
G
g
ijg XZ 11
(1)
where t
ijTRADE are the bilateral trade flows between countries i and j over a given
time period t ; t
iGDP and t
jGDP denote the economic size of both countries; ijDIST is
the geographic distance between their economic centres; and t
iGDPPC and t
jGDPPC are
the respective countries’ per capita income levels capturing factor endowments in the
exporting country and consumption patterns in the importing country. Equation (1) also
includes a vector of time invariant explanatory variables, ijZ ; a vector of time varying
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
trade is defined relative to the sample average rather than in terms of a maximum level
feasible for a given pair of trading partners. Measuring trade potential against mean
predicted values can be problematic because the predictive ability of the gravity model
declines as the year of the inserted values increasingly deviates from the sample average. 2
Under the stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) approach, the gravity equation of
trade determinants identifies the trade frontier. The resulting frontier levels of trade, i.e.
the maximum possible level of trade for a given bilateral trading pair, is impacted by a
random error term which can be positive or negative thereby allowing the stochastic
frontier trade level to vary about the deterministic part of the gravity equation. Observed
trade levels can then be compared against this frontier level of trade for each bilateral
trading pair to assess the scope for trade expansion. The next section provides a detailed
exposition of this approach.
2.2 The Gravity Equation estimated using Stochastic Frontier Analysis
Developed independently by Aigner et al. (1977) and Meeusen and van den Broeck
(1977), stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) has been used extensively in the assessment of
firm performance. In its traditional application, SFA specifies a production frontier
representing the maximum output that can be produced from a given level of inputs.
Fully efficient firms operate on the frontier such that observed and frontier levels of
output coincide, while (technically) inefficient firms operate at a point within the frontier,
signifying a shortfall between the observed and the maximum possible levels of output.
feasible for a given pair of trading partners. Measuring trade potential against mean
predicted values can be problematic because the predictive ability of the gravity model
declines as the year of the inserted values increasingly deviates from the sample average. 2
Under the stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) approach, the gravity equation of
trade determinants identifies the trade frontier. The resulting frontier levels of trade, i.e.
the maximum possible level of trade for a given bilateral trading pair, is impacted by a
random error term which can be positive or negative thereby allowing the stochastic
frontier trade level to vary about the deterministic part of the gravity equation. Observed
trade levels can then be compared against this frontier level of trade for each bilateral
trading pair to assess the scope for trade expansion. The next section provides a detailed
exposition of this approach.
2.2 The Gravity Equation estimated using Stochastic Frontier Analysis
Developed independently by Aigner et al. (1977) and Meeusen and van den Broeck
(1977), stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) has been used extensively in the assessment of
firm performance. In its traditional application, SFA specifies a production frontier
representing the maximum output that can be produced from a given level of inputs.
Fully efficient firms operate on the frontier such that observed and frontier levels of
output coincide, while (technically) inefficient firms operate at a point within the frontier,
signifying a shortfall between the observed and the maximum possible levels of output.
the degree to which actual output falls short of potential output. Analogously, SFA can be
used to define a trade frontier whereby inefficient trade performance refers to the degree
to which actual trade falls short of the maximal, frontier level of trade. This is achieved
by modifying the conventional gravity model (equation 1), as follows:
)exp()exp(),,,,,,( t
ij
t
ij
t
ijij
t
j
t
iij
t
j
t
i
t
ij uvXZGDPPCGDPPCDISTGDPGDPfTRADE (2)
where bilateral trade and its determinants are defined as above and the error term, t
ij , in
equation (1) is now comprised of two parts, viz., a two sided error element, t
ijv ,
representing statistical noise due to measurement error and a one sided inefficiency
element, t
iju , representing a measure of trade performance. Whereas the former term is
assumed to follow a normal distribution, ),0(~ 2
v
t
ij Niidv , as is typical of the
conventional gravity specification, the latter term, t
iju , is assumed to be distributed
independently of the random error and the regressors. This one sided inefficiency
component is a non negative random variable representing technical inefficiency (TE)
and can identify the degree to which observed trade levels deviate from the maximal
possible. Taking a value between zero and unity, a value of zero would imply that the
actual and potential trade levels coincide while values tending towards unity would
indicate scope to raise actual trade levels nearer maximum levels. These deviations from
the maximal trade level can occur due to multilateral resistances (Anderson and van
used to define a trade frontier whereby inefficient trade performance refers to the degree
to which actual trade falls short of the maximal, frontier level of trade. This is achieved
by modifying the conventional gravity model (equation 1), as follows:
)exp()exp(),,,,,,( t
ij
t
ij
t
ijij
t
j
t
iij
t
j
t
i
t
ij uvXZGDPPCGDPPCDISTGDPGDPfTRADE (2)
where bilateral trade and its determinants are defined as above and the error term, t
ij , in
equation (1) is now comprised of two parts, viz., a two sided error element, t
ijv ,
representing statistical noise due to measurement error and a one sided inefficiency
element, t
iju , representing a measure of trade performance. Whereas the former term is
assumed to follow a normal distribution, ),0(~ 2
v
t
ij Niidv , as is typical of the
conventional gravity specification, the latter term, t
iju , is assumed to be distributed
independently of the random error and the regressors. This one sided inefficiency
component is a non negative random variable representing technical inefficiency (TE)
and can identify the degree to which observed trade levels deviate from the maximal
possible. Taking a value between zero and unity, a value of zero would imply that the
actual and potential trade levels coincide while values tending towards unity would
indicate scope to raise actual trade levels nearer maximum levels. These deviations from
the maximal trade level can occur due to multilateral resistances (Anderson and van
Following Aigner et al. (1977), equation (2) is operationalised as a pooled frontier wherein the
parameter values are obtained by maximum likelihood estimation (MLE). Along with the gravity model
parameters, estimates for the variance of the composed error term, 222
uv , and the ratio of the
standard deviation of the inefficiency component to the standard deviation of the random error component,
vu , are also generated. The latter assesses the degree of inefficiency relative to the random error
and when statistically significant, justifies the use of the SFA approach. A further test for the presence of
technical efficiency in the model is undertaken via a one sided likelihood ratio (LR) test of the null
hypothesis, 0: 2
0 uH , against the alternative, 02
0 u:H . Failure to reject the null hypothesis
leads to the SFA model to reduce to an OLS model.
Following parameter estimation, the point estimates of inefficiency can then be obtained as the
mean of the conditional distribution of u given (Jondrow et al. 1982):
2
2
)~(
exp
)~(2
1
)(
),(
)(
u
f
uf
uf
vv
)(
)(
)(
v
t
ij
v
t
ij
v
t
ij
t
ij
t
ij z
z
zuE
(3)
where uv
t
ij
t
ijz 2
and (.) and (.) are the standard normal density and cumulative
distribution functions, respectively. The technical efficiency (TE) estimates for each country pair are then
determined as )exp( t
ij
t
ij uTE .
The full model specification of trade determinants between the Western European countries and
the new EU member states is specified as follows:
tttt COLLOCKDGDPPCDISTGDPGDPEXP
parameter values are obtained by maximum likelihood estimation (MLE). Along with the gravity model
parameters, estimates for the variance of the composed error term, 222
uv , and the ratio of the
standard deviation of the inefficiency component to the standard deviation of the random error component,
vu , are also generated. The latter assesses the degree of inefficiency relative to the random error
and when statistically significant, justifies the use of the SFA approach. A further test for the presence of
technical efficiency in the model is undertaken via a one sided likelihood ratio (LR) test of the null
hypothesis, 0: 2
0 uH , against the alternative, 02
0 u:H . Failure to reject the null hypothesis
leads to the SFA model to reduce to an OLS model.
Following parameter estimation, the point estimates of inefficiency can then be obtained as the
mean of the conditional distribution of u given (Jondrow et al. 1982):
2
2
)~(
exp
)~(2
1
)(
),(
)(
u
f
uf
uf
vv
)(
)(
)(
v
t
ij
v
t
ij
v
t
ij
t
ij
t
ij z
z
zuE
(3)
where uv
t
ij
t
ijz 2
and (.) and (.) are the standard normal density and cumulative
distribution functions, respectively. The technical efficiency (TE) estimates for each country pair are then
determined as )exp( t
ij
t
ij uTE .
The full model specification of trade determinants between the Western European countries and
the new EU member states is specified as follows:
tttt COLLOCKDGDPPCDISTGDPGDPEXP
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
relative terms as the absolute difference in the logged values of GDP per capita income levels,
tj
t
i
t
ij GDPPClnGDPPClnDGDPPC , as a proxy for differences in consumption patterns. The
vector of time invariant explanatory variables, ijZ , comprises a binary coded dummy for landlocked
countries, jLOCK , and a dummy denoting common colonial ties, ijCOL , as an indicator for institutional
proximity. The vector of time varying explanatory variables, t
ijX , refers to the real exchange rate for both
countries, t
iRER and t
jRER , to capture currency price movements. Two additional dummies account for
the EU accession of eight new member states in 2004, t
ijEU 04 , and the later accession of Bulgaria and
Romania in 2007, t
ijEU 07 . All non dummy variables in equation (4) are estimated in logarithmic form.
In its basic form, the standard gravity equation posits that bilateral trade increases with national
income and declines with the distance between them. 4 Larger countries tend to trade more, consistent with
the conduct of much of intraindustry trade between the advanced countries (Helpman and Krugman 1985),
hence the GDP coefficients for both countries should be positively signed. Countries located within close
proximity incur lower transport costs which boosts trade, implying the distance coefficient, ijDIST , should
be negatively signed.
In the augmented version of the gravity model, the separate roles for per capita
income identified by Bergstrand (1989) are merged by Gruber and Vernon (1970) into
the per capita income differential as an indirect way of testing the Linder (1961)
hypothesis. Although Linder presented no formal model, the demand based theory
suggests that if an importing country’s aggregated preferences for goods are similar to an
tj
t
i
t
ij GDPPClnGDPPClnDGDPPC , as a proxy for differences in consumption patterns. The
vector of time invariant explanatory variables, ijZ , comprises a binary coded dummy for landlocked
countries, jLOCK , and a dummy denoting common colonial ties, ijCOL , as an indicator for institutional
proximity. The vector of time varying explanatory variables, t
ijX , refers to the real exchange rate for both
countries, t
iRER and t
jRER , to capture currency price movements. Two additional dummies account for
the EU accession of eight new member states in 2004, t
ijEU 04 , and the later accession of Bulgaria and
Romania in 2007, t
ijEU 07 . All non dummy variables in equation (4) are estimated in logarithmic form.
In its basic form, the standard gravity equation posits that bilateral trade increases with national
income and declines with the distance between them. 4 Larger countries tend to trade more, consistent with
the conduct of much of intraindustry trade between the advanced countries (Helpman and Krugman 1985),
hence the GDP coefficients for both countries should be positively signed. Countries located within close
proximity incur lower transport costs which boosts trade, implying the distance coefficient, ijDIST , should
be negatively signed.
In the augmented version of the gravity model, the separate roles for per capita
income identified by Bergstrand (1989) are merged by Gruber and Vernon (1970) into
the per capita income differential as an indirect way of testing the Linder (1961)
hypothesis. Although Linder presented no formal model, the demand based theory
suggests that if an importing country’s aggregated preferences for goods are similar to an
negative coefficient for the per capita income differential, t
ijDGDPPC , suggesting trade
is positively related to consumers with similar per capita incomes and therefore having
similar consumption patterns, indicates support for the Linder hypothesis. On the other
hand, a positive coefficient will ensue if trade is driven more by differing per capita
incomes consistent with the Heckscher Ohlin model (1919, 1933) of relative factor
abundance.
The dummies included in equation (4) are equal to unity if the new member countries are
landlocked, jLOCK , or if the EU countries share a history of colonial ties, ijCOL . Opposing trade
effects are expected for the respective dummy coefficients. As the overland costs of transporting goods
tends to be higher than shipping costs, landlocked countries located in the heart of Europe tend to be
disadvantaged in trade terms because of their geographical position. In contrast, past governance of another
country can boost present economic links because a coloniser may well have contributed to the state of the
institutions of the colonised.
Motivated by the gravity model derived by Bergstrand (1985), which explicitly includes an
exchange rate index to account for location dependent trade costs, the real exchange rate for both countries,
t
iRER and tjRER , is included to capture the trade effect of currency price movements. Micco et al.
(2003) include the RER for both countries against the US dollar to control for valuation effects, arguing
that a depreciation of the US dollar exchange rate can lower the US dollar value of intra eurozone trade.
The real exchange rate can also be interpreted as a measure of national competitiveness. An increase in the
US real exchange rate (implying a depreciation of the US dollar) improves price competitiveness with
consequential beneficial effects on US exports in foreign markets, but with detrimental effects on US
ijDGDPPC , suggesting trade
is positively related to consumers with similar per capita incomes and therefore having
similar consumption patterns, indicates support for the Linder hypothesis. On the other
hand, a positive coefficient will ensue if trade is driven more by differing per capita
incomes consistent with the Heckscher Ohlin model (1919, 1933) of relative factor
abundance.
The dummies included in equation (4) are equal to unity if the new member countries are
landlocked, jLOCK , or if the EU countries share a history of colonial ties, ijCOL . Opposing trade
effects are expected for the respective dummy coefficients. As the overland costs of transporting goods
tends to be higher than shipping costs, landlocked countries located in the heart of Europe tend to be
disadvantaged in trade terms because of their geographical position. In contrast, past governance of another
country can boost present economic links because a coloniser may well have contributed to the state of the
institutions of the colonised.
Motivated by the gravity model derived by Bergstrand (1985), which explicitly includes an
exchange rate index to account for location dependent trade costs, the real exchange rate for both countries,
t
iRER and tjRER , is included to capture the trade effect of currency price movements. Micco et al.
(2003) include the RER for both countries against the US dollar to control for valuation effects, arguing
that a depreciation of the US dollar exchange rate can lower the US dollar value of intra eurozone trade.
The real exchange rate can also be interpreted as a measure of national competitiveness. An increase in the
US real exchange rate (implying a depreciation of the US dollar) improves price competitiveness with
consequential beneficial effects on US exports in foreign markets, but with detrimental effects on US
additional countries joined in 2007. In a similar vein, Aitken (1973) examined the trade effects of the
dummy variables denoting the European Economic Community (EEC) and the European Free Trade
Association (EFTA) over the period 1951 1967 to assess the importance of regional integration within a
gravity model framework.
The panel data set consists of bilateral export flows from 17 Western European
countries comprising the 14 established EU countries (Belgium and Luxembourg are
treated as a single country) and three EFTA member countries5 to 10 new member states6
over the period 1994 to 2007. The sample period covers the transformation phase from
communism to EU accession and ends in 2007 to avoid the effects of the global financial
crisis leading to very abnormal trade flows.
The data sources are as follows. Nominal export flow data, denominated in US
dollars at constant 2000 prices, are obtained from the Direction of Trade Statistics
(DOTS), International Monetary Fund (IMF). The export data are expressed in real terms
based on US producer prices (2000 = 100), sourced from the International Financial
Statistics (IFS), IMF. Data on GDP and GDP per capita at constant 2000 US dollars are
from the World Development Indicators (WDI), World Bank. The geographic distance,
measured in kilometres between the economic centres of the trading partner countries, are
from the CEPII as are the colonial and the landlocked dummies.
Nominal exchange rates are official exchange rates in local currency units (LCU)
per US dollar, sourced from the WDI, World Bank. The exchange rates for each country
dummy variables denoting the European Economic Community (EEC) and the European Free Trade
Association (EFTA) over the period 1951 1967 to assess the importance of regional integration within a
gravity model framework.
The panel data set consists of bilateral export flows from 17 Western European
countries comprising the 14 established EU countries (Belgium and Luxembourg are
treated as a single country) and three EFTA member countries5 to 10 new member states6
over the period 1994 to 2007. The sample period covers the transformation phase from
communism to EU accession and ends in 2007 to avoid the effects of the global financial
crisis leading to very abnormal trade flows.
The data sources are as follows. Nominal export flow data, denominated in US
dollars at constant 2000 prices, are obtained from the Direction of Trade Statistics
(DOTS), International Monetary Fund (IMF). The export data are expressed in real terms
based on US producer prices (2000 = 100), sourced from the International Financial
Statistics (IFS), IMF. Data on GDP and GDP per capita at constant 2000 US dollars are
from the World Development Indicators (WDI), World Bank. The geographic distance,
measured in kilometres between the economic centres of the trading partner countries, are
from the CEPII as are the colonial and the landlocked dummies.
Nominal exchange rates are official exchange rates in local currency units (LCU)
per US dollar, sourced from the WDI, World Bank. The exchange rates for each country
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
i and j vis a vis the US dollar are expressed as a ratio of goods prices abroad to
domestic prices where prices refer to consumer prices (2000 = 100), obtained from the
IFS, IMF. The summary statistics for the model variables are shown in Table 1.
[Insert Table 1 here]
3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
3.1 Gravity Model Estimates
Table 2 presents the results for the stochastic frontier specification of the gravity model
of exports from 17 Western European countries to 10 new member states estimated by
maximum likelihood over the 1994 2007 period. Column (1) shows the results for the
baseline model (equation 4). Column (2) augments the baseline model with time specific
effects to control for common shocks affecting all countries in the sample. Column (3)
additionally includes country specific effects capturing varying country characteristics
among the new member states. Interacting the specific effects in columns (2) and (3),
column (4) allows for variation of country characteristics over time. Baier and Bergstrand
(2007) have previously highlighted the benefits of using country time interactions to
account for time variation of multilateral trade resistances.
[Insert Table 2 here]
Two tests confirm the appropriateness of the SFA approach to estimating the gravity model. In
rejecting the null hypothesis, 0: 2
0 uH , against the alternative, 02
1 u:H , the likelihood ratio
domestic prices where prices refer to consumer prices (2000 = 100), obtained from the
IFS, IMF. The summary statistics for the model variables are shown in Table 1.
[Insert Table 1 here]
3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
3.1 Gravity Model Estimates
Table 2 presents the results for the stochastic frontier specification of the gravity model
of exports from 17 Western European countries to 10 new member states estimated by
maximum likelihood over the 1994 2007 period. Column (1) shows the results for the
baseline model (equation 4). Column (2) augments the baseline model with time specific
effects to control for common shocks affecting all countries in the sample. Column (3)
additionally includes country specific effects capturing varying country characteristics
among the new member states. Interacting the specific effects in columns (2) and (3),
column (4) allows for variation of country characteristics over time. Baier and Bergstrand
(2007) have previously highlighted the benefits of using country time interactions to
account for time variation of multilateral trade resistances.
[Insert Table 2 here]
Two tests confirm the appropriateness of the SFA approach to estimating the gravity model. In
rejecting the null hypothesis, 0: 2
0 uH , against the alternative, 02
1 u:H , the likelihood ratio
indicating that the level of inefficiency is 1.08 times that of the random error. A similar result is found
consistently across the estimated models in support of the SFA approach.
Regarding the core gravity parameter estimates, the positive and significant
coefficient estimates for GDP suggest larger countries trade more. Trade related costs,
however, reduce the volume of trade as indicated by the distance coefficients. In support
of the Heckscher Ohlin model the per capita income difference coefficients suggest factor
endowments are sufficiently different between Western Europe and the new EU member
countries, although its declining magnitude and significance suggests the gap is closing
over time.
With the exception of column (3), the trade inhibiting effect of geographical
characteristics is apparent across all specifications for the landlocked countries (the
Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia). The negative effect becomes insignificant when
country time interactions are introduced in column (4), suggesting the partition effects of
geography diminish over time. In contrast, historical colonial links (between Austria vis à
vis the Czech Republic and Slovenia; Germany and Poland; and Sweden and Estonia)
increase bilateral trade flows, but not significantly.
The sustained depreciation of the dollar after the launch of the euro suggests
valuation effects (Micco et al., 2003) and/or volume effects transmitted via changes to the
terms of trade negatively affect European exports. A similarly negative coefficient for the
importing countries’ RER is shown in columns (3) and (4), not surprising given the new
consistently across the estimated models in support of the SFA approach.
Regarding the core gravity parameter estimates, the positive and significant
coefficient estimates for GDP suggest larger countries trade more. Trade related costs,
however, reduce the volume of trade as indicated by the distance coefficients. In support
of the Heckscher Ohlin model the per capita income difference coefficients suggest factor
endowments are sufficiently different between Western Europe and the new EU member
countries, although its declining magnitude and significance suggests the gap is closing
over time.
With the exception of column (3), the trade inhibiting effect of geographical
characteristics is apparent across all specifications for the landlocked countries (the
Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia). The negative effect becomes insignificant when
country time interactions are introduced in column (4), suggesting the partition effects of
geography diminish over time. In contrast, historical colonial links (between Austria vis à
vis the Czech Republic and Slovenia; Germany and Poland; and Sweden and Estonia)
increase bilateral trade flows, but not significantly.
The sustained depreciation of the dollar after the launch of the euro suggests
valuation effects (Micco et al., 2003) and/or volume effects transmitted via changes to the
terms of trade negatively affect European exports. A similarly negative coefficient for the
importing countries’ RER is shown in columns (3) and (4), not surprising given the new
Finally, the positive and in general significant coefficient estimates for the EU
dummies confirm the trade enhancing effect of regional integration. The relatively higher
magnitude for the EU07 dummy suggests the efficiency gains of regional integration are
stronger for the two newest member countries. Overall, the results for the preferred
stochastic frontier specification of trade determinants provide a reasonable approximation
of the factors governing bilateral trade patterns between Western Europe and the new
member states over the 1994 2007 period.
3.2 Trade Efficiency Scores
The trade efficiency scores for each bilateral pair of countries associated with the preferred stochastic
frontier specification (column 4), averaged over the years 1994 2007, are shown in Table 3. A zero value
for the one sided term, t
iju , indicates the inefficiency term reduces to the random noise component thereby
rendering actual and maximum trade levels coincident. More realistic is a non zero value for the
inefficiency term, t
iju , indicating deviations of actual trade from frontier estimates and hence, scope for
further trade integration. Point estimates of technical efficiency (TE) are then obtained for each bilateral
pair as )exp( t
ij
t
ij uTE . High efficiency scores suggest trade between two countries is close to their
maximum trade potential whereas low efficiency scores indicate deviations of actual trade from frontier
estimates, implying scope for further trade integration.
[Insert Table 3 here]
Most country pairs exhibit a high degree of trade integration, but with some
notable exceptions. The highly integrated countries include the big four (Czech Republic,
dummies confirm the trade enhancing effect of regional integration. The relatively higher
magnitude for the EU07 dummy suggests the efficiency gains of regional integration are
stronger for the two newest member countries. Overall, the results for the preferred
stochastic frontier specification of trade determinants provide a reasonable approximation
of the factors governing bilateral trade patterns between Western Europe and the new
member states over the 1994 2007 period.
3.2 Trade Efficiency Scores
The trade efficiency scores for each bilateral pair of countries associated with the preferred stochastic
frontier specification (column 4), averaged over the years 1994 2007, are shown in Table 3. A zero value
for the one sided term, t
iju , indicates the inefficiency term reduces to the random noise component thereby
rendering actual and maximum trade levels coincident. More realistic is a non zero value for the
inefficiency term, t
iju , indicating deviations of actual trade from frontier estimates and hence, scope for
further trade integration. Point estimates of technical efficiency (TE) are then obtained for each bilateral
pair as )exp( t
ij
t
ij uTE . High efficiency scores suggest trade between two countries is close to their
maximum trade potential whereas low efficiency scores indicate deviations of actual trade from frontier
estimates, implying scope for further trade integration.
[Insert Table 3 here]
Most country pairs exhibit a high degree of trade integration, but with some
notable exceptions. The highly integrated countries include the big four (Czech Republic,
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
programme of liberalisation. At the same time, mixed efficiency scores are also in
evidence, depending on the partner country. For example, while attaining relatively high
efficiency scores vis à vis many Western partners, Hungary and Slovakia perform poorly
against others – Greece, Iceland and Norway in particular.
Several features characterise the high mean efficiency scores. First, geographical
proximity plays a key role. Close trade alliances are in evidence, for example, between
the Baltics (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania) and the Nordic countries (Denmark, Finland
and Iceland); between Austria and the two latest accession countries; between Greece and
Bulgaria; and between Italy and Romania. Second, the new members tend to perform best
vis à vis the smaller and more open economies (Belgium and the Netherlands).
Finally, the contribution of regionalism to trade patterns is also apparent.
Although bilateral trade agreements are in force between the EU and the individual
EFTA member countries, the mean efficiency scores tend to be higher vis à vis the EU15
– Iceland and Norway are particularly low in comparison. Some exceptions to this pattern
among the EU15 exist. Together with the UK, lower than average trade performance
between the 10 new member countries and Greece is evident, perhaps not unrelated to its
declining competitiveness over time.
On the whole, the efficiency scores are consistent with the rapid reorientation of
trade towards Western Europe, with each new member state achieving close to two thirds
of frontier estimates over the 1994 2007 period. The high efficiency scores suggest a low
evidence, depending on the partner country. For example, while attaining relatively high
efficiency scores vis à vis many Western partners, Hungary and Slovakia perform poorly
against others – Greece, Iceland and Norway in particular.
Several features characterise the high mean efficiency scores. First, geographical
proximity plays a key role. Close trade alliances are in evidence, for example, between
the Baltics (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania) and the Nordic countries (Denmark, Finland
and Iceland); between Austria and the two latest accession countries; between Greece and
Bulgaria; and between Italy and Romania. Second, the new members tend to perform best
vis à vis the smaller and more open economies (Belgium and the Netherlands).
Finally, the contribution of regionalism to trade patterns is also apparent.
Although bilateral trade agreements are in force between the EU and the individual
EFTA member countries, the mean efficiency scores tend to be higher vis à vis the EU15
– Iceland and Norway are particularly low in comparison. Some exceptions to this pattern
among the EU15 exist. Together with the UK, lower than average trade performance
between the 10 new member countries and Greece is evident, perhaps not unrelated to its
declining competitiveness over time.
On the whole, the efficiency scores are consistent with the rapid reorientation of
trade towards Western Europe, with each new member state achieving close to two thirds
of frontier estimates over the 1994 2007 period. The high efficiency scores suggest a low
and Pentecost 2010). The main exceptions to the broad pattern of high integration levels
suggest greatest potential for trade expansion vis à vis Greece, Iceland, Norway and the
UK.
4. CONCLUSIONS
The breakup of the Soviet Union ushered in a new era of trade expansion between the
excommunist countries and their Western neigbouring countries. In anticipation of a
reorientation of CEE trade towards Western Europe, early studies sought to quantify the
volume of trade likely to prevail in an East–West trade direction assuming full economic
liberalisation. Typically, the degree of East–West trade integration is assessed by
comparing actual trade volumes with potential trade volumes using the gravity model
parameters that fit a model of a normal country’s geographic patterns. This approach,
however, does not gauge trade levels against a maximum level of trade feasible for the
group of eastern European countries.
Using a stochastic frontier approach to estimating the gravity equation for a panel
of exports from 17 Western European countries to the 10 new EU member countries over
the transformation period of 1994 2007, the efficiency of East–West trade integration is
identified relative to maximum potential levels. If two countries achieve an efficient level
of trade, they will operate on the trade frontier and thus reach their maximum trade
potential otherwise deviations from the trade frontier indicate inefficient levels of trade,
suggest greatest potential for trade expansion vis à vis Greece, Iceland, Norway and the
UK.
4. CONCLUSIONS
The breakup of the Soviet Union ushered in a new era of trade expansion between the
excommunist countries and their Western neigbouring countries. In anticipation of a
reorientation of CEE trade towards Western Europe, early studies sought to quantify the
volume of trade likely to prevail in an East–West trade direction assuming full economic
liberalisation. Typically, the degree of East–West trade integration is assessed by
comparing actual trade volumes with potential trade volumes using the gravity model
parameters that fit a model of a normal country’s geographic patterns. This approach,
however, does not gauge trade levels against a maximum level of trade feasible for the
group of eastern European countries.
Using a stochastic frontier approach to estimating the gravity equation for a panel
of exports from 17 Western European countries to the 10 new EU member countries over
the transformation period of 1994 2007, the efficiency of East–West trade integration is
identified relative to maximum potential levels. If two countries achieve an efficient level
of trade, they will operate on the trade frontier and thus reach their maximum trade
potential otherwise deviations from the trade frontier indicate inefficient levels of trade,
The main exceptions to the broad pattern of high integration levels suggest greatest
potential for trade expansion vis à vis Greece, Iceland, Norway and the UK.
potential for trade expansion vis à vis Greece, Iceland, Norway and the UK.
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
REFERENCES
Aigner, Dennis, Lovell, C. A. Knox, Schmidt, Peter, 1977. Formulation and estimation of
stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics 6, 21-37.
Aitken, Norman D., 1973. The effect of the EEC and EFTA on European trade: a
temporal cross-section analysis. American Economic Review 63, 881-892.
Anderson, James E., 1979. A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American
Economic Review 69, 106-116.
Anderson, James E, van Wincoop, Eric, 2003. Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the
border puzzle. American Economic Review 93, 170-192.
Armington, Paul S., 1969. A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of
Production. IMF Staff Papers, 16, 159-178.
Armstrong, Shiro, Drysdale, Peter, Kalirajan, Kaliappa, 2008. Asian trade structures and
trade potential: an initial analysis of South and East Asian trade. Working Paper
Series No. 32. EABER, Canberra.
Baier, Scott L., Bergstrand, Jeffrey H., 2007. Do free trade agreements actually increase
members’ international trade?. Journal of International Economics 71, 72-95.
Baldwin, Richard E., 1994. Towards an integrated Europe. CEPR, London.
Bergstrand, Jeffrey H., 1985. The gravity equation in international trade: some
Aigner, Dennis, Lovell, C. A. Knox, Schmidt, Peter, 1977. Formulation and estimation of
stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics 6, 21-37.
Aitken, Norman D., 1973. The effect of the EEC and EFTA on European trade: a
temporal cross-section analysis. American Economic Review 63, 881-892.
Anderson, James E., 1979. A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American
Economic Review 69, 106-116.
Anderson, James E, van Wincoop, Eric, 2003. Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the
border puzzle. American Economic Review 93, 170-192.
Armington, Paul S., 1969. A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of
Production. IMF Staff Papers, 16, 159-178.
Armstrong, Shiro, Drysdale, Peter, Kalirajan, Kaliappa, 2008. Asian trade structures and
trade potential: an initial analysis of South and East Asian trade. Working Paper
Series No. 32. EABER, Canberra.
Baier, Scott L., Bergstrand, Jeffrey H., 2007. Do free trade agreements actually increase
members’ international trade?. Journal of International Economics 71, 72-95.
Baldwin, Richard E., 1994. Towards an integrated Europe. CEPR, London.
Bergstrand, Jeffrey H., 1985. The gravity equation in international trade: some
Bergstrand, Jeffrey H., 1989. The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic
competition, and the factor-proportions theory in international trade. Review of
Economics and Statistics 71, 143-153.
Bussière, Matthieu, Fidrmuc, Jarko, Schnatz, Bernd, 2005. Trade integration of Central
and Eastern European countries: lessons from a gravity model. Working Paper
Series No. 545. ECB, Frankfurt.
Centre d’etudes prospectives et d’informations internationales (CEPII), 2011. Available
at http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm. CEPII, Paris.
Drysdale, Peter, Huang, Yiping, Kalirajan, Kaliappa 2000. China’s trade efficiency:
measurement and determinants. In: Drysdale, Peter, Zhang, Yunling, Song, Ligang
(Eds.), APEC and liberalisation of the Chinese economy. Asia Pacific Press,
Canberra, pp. 259-271.
Gros, Daniel, Gonciarz Andrzej, 1996. A note on the trade potential of Central and
Eastern Europe. European Journal of Political Economy 12, 709-721.
Gruber, William H., Vernon, Raymond, 1970. The technology factor in a world trade
matrix. In: Vernon, Raymond (Ed.), The technology factor in international trade.
Columbia University Press, New York/London, pp.233-272.
Heckscher, Eli, 1919. The effects of foreign trade on the distribution of income.
Ekonomisk Tidskrift 21, 497-512.
competition, and the factor-proportions theory in international trade. Review of
Economics and Statistics 71, 143-153.
Bussière, Matthieu, Fidrmuc, Jarko, Schnatz, Bernd, 2005. Trade integration of Central
and Eastern European countries: lessons from a gravity model. Working Paper
Series No. 545. ECB, Frankfurt.
Centre d’etudes prospectives et d’informations internationales (CEPII), 2011. Available
at http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm. CEPII, Paris.
Drysdale, Peter, Huang, Yiping, Kalirajan, Kaliappa 2000. China’s trade efficiency:
measurement and determinants. In: Drysdale, Peter, Zhang, Yunling, Song, Ligang
(Eds.), APEC and liberalisation of the Chinese economy. Asia Pacific Press,
Canberra, pp. 259-271.
Gros, Daniel, Gonciarz Andrzej, 1996. A note on the trade potential of Central and
Eastern Europe. European Journal of Political Economy 12, 709-721.
Gruber, William H., Vernon, Raymond, 1970. The technology factor in a world trade
matrix. In: Vernon, Raymond (Ed.), The technology factor in international trade.
Columbia University Press, New York/London, pp.233-272.
Heckscher, Eli, 1919. The effects of foreign trade on the distribution of income.
Ekonomisk Tidskrift 21, 497-512.
International Monetary Fund (IMF), Direction of Trade Statistics (DOTS) October 2011,
ESDS International, (Mimas) University of Manchester.
International Monetary Fund (IMF), International Financial Statistics (IFS) June 2011,
ESDS International, (Mimas) University of Manchester.
Jondrow, James, Lovell, C.A. Knox, Materov, Ivan S., Schmidt, Peter, 1982. On the
estimation of technical inefficiency in the stochastic frontier production function
model. Journal of Econometrics 19, 233-238.
Kalirajan, Kaliappa, Singh, Kanhaiya, 2008. A comparative analysis of China’s and
India’s recent export performances. Asian Economic Papers 7, 1-28.
Linder, Staffan. B., 1961. An essay on trade and transformation. John Wiley and Sons,
New York.
Meeusen, Wim, van den Broeck, Julien, 1977. Efficiency estimation from Cobb-Douglas
production functions with composed error. International Economic Review 18, 435-
444.
Micco, Alejandro, Stein, Ernesto, Ordoñez, Guillermo, 2003. The currency union effect
on trade: early evidence from EMU. Economic Policy 18, 315-356.
Nilsson, Lars, 2000. Trade integration and the EU economic membership criteria.
European Journal of Political Economy 16, 807-827.
ESDS International, (Mimas) University of Manchester.
International Monetary Fund (IMF), International Financial Statistics (IFS) June 2011,
ESDS International, (Mimas) University of Manchester.
Jondrow, James, Lovell, C.A. Knox, Materov, Ivan S., Schmidt, Peter, 1982. On the
estimation of technical inefficiency in the stochastic frontier production function
model. Journal of Econometrics 19, 233-238.
Kalirajan, Kaliappa, Singh, Kanhaiya, 2008. A comparative analysis of China’s and
India’s recent export performances. Asian Economic Papers 7, 1-28.
Linder, Staffan. B., 1961. An essay on trade and transformation. John Wiley and Sons,
New York.
Meeusen, Wim, van den Broeck, Julien, 1977. Efficiency estimation from Cobb-Douglas
production functions with composed error. International Economic Review 18, 435-
444.
Micco, Alejandro, Stein, Ernesto, Ordoñez, Guillermo, 2003. The currency union effect
on trade: early evidence from EMU. Economic Policy 18, 315-356.
Nilsson, Lars, 2000. Trade integration and the EU economic membership criteria.
European Journal of Political Economy 16, 807-827.
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
Stack, Marie M., Pentecost, Eric J., 2010. A gravity model approach to estimating
prospective trade gains in the EU accession and associated countries. Discussion
Papers in Economics No. 11. NTU, Nottingham.
Tinbergen, Jan, 1962. Shaping the world economy: suggestions for an international
economic policy. Twentieth Century Fund, New York.
World Bank (WB), World Development Indicators (WDI) April 2011, ESDS
International, (Mimas) University of Manchester.
prospective trade gains in the EU accession and associated countries. Discussion
Papers in Economics No. 11. NTU, Nottingham.
Tinbergen, Jan, 1962. Shaping the world economy: suggestions for an international
economic policy. Twentieth Century Fund, New York.
World Bank (WB), World Development Indicators (WDI) April 2011, ESDS
International, (Mimas) University of Manchester.
Figure 1 Trade Shares with the EU and the EFTA Countries
a Source: Direction of Trade Statistics, International Monetary Fund.
a Source: Direction of Trade Statistics, International Monetary Fund.
Table 1 Summary Statistics
Variable Mean Standard
deviation
Minimum Maximum No. of obs
Exports 18.82 2.21 5.32 24.37 2359
Exporter GDP 26.26 1.27 22.65 28.36 2380
Importer GDP 23.96 0.98 22.11 26.14 2380
Distance 7.15 0.63 4.09 8.22 2380
GDP per capita difference 1.70 0.61 0.38 × 10–2 3.26 2380
Landlocked 0.30 0.46 0.00 1.00 2380
Colony 0.02 0.15 0.00 1.00 2380
Exporter RER 5.11 1.25 3.90 9.15 2370
Importer RER 6.95 1.91 3.77 10.25 2363
EU-2004 0.19 0.39 0.00 1.00 2380
EU-2007 0.02 0.11 0.00 1.00 2380
Variable Mean Standard
deviation
Minimum Maximum No. of obs
Exports 18.82 2.21 5.32 24.37 2359
Exporter GDP 26.26 1.27 22.65 28.36 2380
Importer GDP 23.96 0.98 22.11 26.14 2380
Distance 7.15 0.63 4.09 8.22 2380
GDP per capita difference 1.70 0.61 0.38 × 10–2 3.26 2380
Landlocked 0.30 0.46 0.00 1.00 2380
Colony 0.02 0.15 0.00 1.00 2380
Exporter RER 5.11 1.25 3.90 9.15 2370
Importer RER 6.95 1.91 3.77 10.25 2363
EU-2004 0.19 0.39 0.00 1.00 2380
EU-2007 0.02 0.11 0.00 1.00 2380
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
Table 2 A Stochastic Frontier Specification of EU and EFTA–NMS Export Determinants
Regressors (1)a (2)a (3)a (4)a
Exporter GDP 0.90**
(0.02)
0.87**
(0.02)
0.88**
(0.02)
0.87**
(0.02)
Importer GDP 0.83**
(0.02)
0.81**
(0.02)
0.85**
(0.22)
0.98**
(0.08)
Distance –1.47**
(0.03)
–1.49**
(0.03)
–1.55**
(0.03)
–1.54**
(0.03)
GDP per capita difference 0.29**
(0.04)
0.34**
(0.04)
0.07
(0.06)
0.09
(0.06)
Landlocked –0.26**
(0.04)
–0.28**
(0.04)
1.51**
(0.50)
–0.17
(0.80)
Colony 0.10
(0.10)
0.09
(0.10)
0.03
(0.09)
0.03
(0.09)
Exporter RER –0.12**
(0.02)
–0.15**
(0.02)
–0.11**
(0.02)
–0.10**
(0.02)
Importer RER 0.03**
(0.01)
0.07**
(0.01)
–0.80**
(0.16)
–0.07
(0.36)
EU-2004 0.44**
(0.04)
0.11
(0.07)
0.07
(0.07)
0.29**
(0.09)
EU-2007 0.78**
(0.14)
0.33**
(0.15)
0.28*
(0.15)
0.86**
(0.29)
Intercept –13.83**
(0.70)
–13.13**
(0.68)
–8.55*
(5.03)
–15.33**
(2.80)
b 1.08**
(0.04)
1.18**
(0.04)
1.22**
(0.03)
1.30**
(0.04)
u2
c –1.05**
(0.09)
–1.03**
(0.09)
–1.10**
(0.09)
–1.07**
(0.09)
No. of obs 2332 2332 2332 2332
2 d 250** 290** 300** 310**
Regressors (1)a (2)a (3)a (4)a
Exporter GDP 0.90**
(0.02)
0.87**
(0.02)
0.88**
(0.02)
0.87**
(0.02)
Importer GDP 0.83**
(0.02)
0.81**
(0.02)
0.85**
(0.22)
0.98**
(0.08)
Distance –1.47**
(0.03)
–1.49**
(0.03)
–1.55**
(0.03)
–1.54**
(0.03)
GDP per capita difference 0.29**
(0.04)
0.34**
(0.04)
0.07
(0.06)
0.09
(0.06)
Landlocked –0.26**
(0.04)
–0.28**
(0.04)
1.51**
(0.50)
–0.17
(0.80)
Colony 0.10
(0.10)
0.09
(0.10)
0.03
(0.09)
0.03
(0.09)
Exporter RER –0.12**
(0.02)
–0.15**
(0.02)
–0.11**
(0.02)
–0.10**
(0.02)
Importer RER 0.03**
(0.01)
0.07**
(0.01)
–0.80**
(0.16)
–0.07
(0.36)
EU-2004 0.44**
(0.04)
0.11
(0.07)
0.07
(0.07)
0.29**
(0.09)
EU-2007 0.78**
(0.14)
0.33**
(0.15)
0.28*
(0.15)
0.86**
(0.29)
Intercept –13.83**
(0.70)
–13.13**
(0.68)
–8.55*
(5.03)
–15.33**
(2.80)
b 1.08**
(0.04)
1.18**
(0.04)
1.22**
(0.03)
1.30**
(0.04)
u2
c –1.05**
(0.09)
–1.03**
(0.09)
–1.10**
(0.09)
–1.07**
(0.09)
No. of obs 2332 2332 2332 2332
2 d 250** 290** 300** 310**
27
Table 3 Efficiency Score Estimates from the Stochastic Frontier Specification of the Gravity Model, 1994-2007a
AUT BEL DNK FIN FRA DEU GRC IRL ISL ITA NLD NOR PRT ESP SWE CHE UKK
BGR 0.75 0.80 0.71 0.68 0.68 0.78 0.82 0.63 0.34 0.65 0.79 0.19 0.61 0.63 0.72 0.67 0.53
CZE 0.63 0.79 0.52 0.78 0.64 0.63 0.47 0.81 0.22 0.74 0.76 0.67 0.60 0.80 0.79 0.61 0.58
EST 0.66 0.82 0.81 0.46 0.55 0.69 0.26 0.72 0.70 0.75 0.81 0.55 0.58 0.68 0.76 0.51 0.55
HUN 0.58 0.83 0.56 0.80 0.66 0.80 0.25 0.77 0.20 0.65 0.80 0.17 0.74 0.74 0.77 0.61 0.53
LVA 0.60 0.81 0.78 0.72 0.53 0.67 0.33 0.59 0.82 0.73 0.80 0.67 0.54 0.63 0.67 0.64 0.52
LTU 0.41 0.80 0.80 0.71 0.54 0.65 0.28 0.43 0.91 0.70 0.76 0.57 0.55 0.72 0.68 0.55 0.48
POL 0.53 0.83 0.63 0.72 0.70 0.63 0.37 0.74 0.66 0.79 0.81 0.61 0.59 0.79 0.72 0.64 0.56
ROM 0.78 0.81 0.53 0.42 0.77 0.80 0.62 0.69 0.20 0.83 0.80 0.33 0.50 0.64 0.70 0.65 0.62
SVK 0.12 0.82 0.61 0.78 0.69 0.81 0.33 0.71 0.24 0.74 0.79 0.37 0.66 0.80 0.76 0.62 0.47
SVN 0.77 0.76 0.60 0.72 0.79 0.79 0.44 0.64 0.23 0.76 0.77 0.42 0.37 0.79 0.80 0.47 0.42
a Efficiency scores are derived from the parameter estimates of the preferred specification, column 4, Table 2.
Table 3 Efficiency Score Estimates from the Stochastic Frontier Specification of the Gravity Model, 1994-2007a
AUT BEL DNK FIN FRA DEU GRC IRL ISL ITA NLD NOR PRT ESP SWE CHE UKK
BGR 0.75 0.80 0.71 0.68 0.68 0.78 0.82 0.63 0.34 0.65 0.79 0.19 0.61 0.63 0.72 0.67 0.53
CZE 0.63 0.79 0.52 0.78 0.64 0.63 0.47 0.81 0.22 0.74 0.76 0.67 0.60 0.80 0.79 0.61 0.58
EST 0.66 0.82 0.81 0.46 0.55 0.69 0.26 0.72 0.70 0.75 0.81 0.55 0.58 0.68 0.76 0.51 0.55
HUN 0.58 0.83 0.56 0.80 0.66 0.80 0.25 0.77 0.20 0.65 0.80 0.17 0.74 0.74 0.77 0.61 0.53
LVA 0.60 0.81 0.78 0.72 0.53 0.67 0.33 0.59 0.82 0.73 0.80 0.67 0.54 0.63 0.67 0.64 0.52
LTU 0.41 0.80 0.80 0.71 0.54 0.65 0.28 0.43 0.91 0.70 0.76 0.57 0.55 0.72 0.68 0.55 0.48
POL 0.53 0.83 0.63 0.72 0.70 0.63 0.37 0.74 0.66 0.79 0.81 0.61 0.59 0.79 0.72 0.64 0.56
ROM 0.78 0.81 0.53 0.42 0.77 0.80 0.62 0.69 0.20 0.83 0.80 0.33 0.50 0.64 0.70 0.65 0.62
SVK 0.12 0.82 0.61 0.78 0.69 0.81 0.33 0.71 0.24 0.74 0.79 0.37 0.66 0.80 0.76 0.62 0.47
SVN 0.77 0.76 0.60 0.72 0.79 0.79 0.44 0.64 0.23 0.76 0.77 0.42 0.37 0.79 0.80 0.47 0.42
a Efficiency scores are derived from the parameter estimates of the preferred specification, column 4, Table 2.
DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS
2013/4
2013/3
2013/2
2013/1
2012/3
2012/2
2012/1
2011/4
2011/3
2011/2
2011/1
2010/11
2010/10
2010/9
Geetha Ravishankar and Marie Stack, The Gravity Model and Trade
Efficiency: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis of Potential Trade.
Chunping Liu and Patrick Minford, How Important is the Credit Channel? An
Empirical Study of the US Banking Crisis.
Chunping Liu and Patrick Minford, Comparing Behavioural and Rational
Expectations for the US Post-War Economy.
Dan Wheatley, Is it good to share? Debating patterns in availability and use
of job share.
Simeon Coleman and Vitor Leone, Time-Series Characteristics Of UK
Commercial Property Returns: Testing For Multiple Changes In Persistence .
Otavio Ribeiro de Medeiros and Vitor Leone, Multiple Changes in Persistence
vs. Explosive Behaviour: The Dotcom Bubble.
Rob Ackrill and Simeon Coleman, Inflation Dynamics In Central And Eastern
European Countries.
Simeon Coleman, Inflation Dynamics and Poverty Rates: Regional and
Sectoral Evidence for Ghana.
Dan Wheatley and Zhongmin Wu, Work, Inequality, And The Dual Career
Household.
Simeon Coleman and Kavita Sirichand, Fractional Integration and the
Volatility Of UK Interest Rates.
Simeon Coleman, Investigating Business Cycle Synchronization In West
Africa.
Marie Stack and Eric Pentecost, A Gravity Model Approach To Estimating
Prospective Trade Gains in The EU Accession And Associated Countries.
Vitor Leone And Bruce Philp, Surplus-Value And Aggregate Concentration In
The UK Economy, 1987-2009.
Robert Ackrill and Adrian Kay, WTO Regulations and Bioenergy
Sustainability Certification – Synergies and Possible Conflicts.
2013/4
2013/3
2013/2
2013/1
2012/3
2012/2
2012/1
2011/4
2011/3
2011/2
2011/1
2010/11
2010/10
2010/9
Geetha Ravishankar and Marie Stack, The Gravity Model and Trade
Efficiency: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis of Potential Trade.
Chunping Liu and Patrick Minford, How Important is the Credit Channel? An
Empirical Study of the US Banking Crisis.
Chunping Liu and Patrick Minford, Comparing Behavioural and Rational
Expectations for the US Post-War Economy.
Dan Wheatley, Is it good to share? Debating patterns in availability and use
of job share.
Simeon Coleman and Vitor Leone, Time-Series Characteristics Of UK
Commercial Property Returns: Testing For Multiple Changes In Persistence .
Otavio Ribeiro de Medeiros and Vitor Leone, Multiple Changes in Persistence
vs. Explosive Behaviour: The Dotcom Bubble.
Rob Ackrill and Simeon Coleman, Inflation Dynamics In Central And Eastern
European Countries.
Simeon Coleman, Inflation Dynamics and Poverty Rates: Regional and
Sectoral Evidence for Ghana.
Dan Wheatley and Zhongmin Wu, Work, Inequality, And The Dual Career
Household.
Simeon Coleman and Kavita Sirichand, Fractional Integration and the
Volatility Of UK Interest Rates.
Simeon Coleman, Investigating Business Cycle Synchronization In West
Africa.
Marie Stack and Eric Pentecost, A Gravity Model Approach To Estimating
Prospective Trade Gains in The EU Accession And Associated Countries.
Vitor Leone And Bruce Philp, Surplus-Value And Aggregate Concentration In
The UK Economy, 1987-2009.
Robert Ackrill and Adrian Kay, WTO Regulations and Bioenergy
Sustainability Certification – Synergies and Possible Conflicts.
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
2010/4
2010/3
2010/2
2010/1
2009/7
2009/6
2009/5
2009/4
2009/3
2009/2
2009/1
2008/16
2008/15
and public agendas: testing for media effects in Argentina Turing the
Kirchner administration
Vitor Leone, From property companies to real estate investment trusts: the
impact of economic and property factors in the UK commercial property
returns
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Paulo José Regis, Purchasing power parity in OECD
countries: nonlinear unit root tests revisited
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Bruce Philp, Exploitation and the class struggle
Barry Harrison and Winston Moore, Nonlinearities in Stock Returns for Some
Recent Entrants to the EU
Joao R. Faria, Le Wang and Zhongmin Wu, Debts on debts
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Luis A. Gil-Alana, Unemployment hysteresis,
structural changes,non-linearities and fractional integration in Central and
Eastern Europe
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Javier Ordóñez, Unemployment and common
smooth transition trends in Central and Eastern European Countries
Stephen Dobson and Carlyn Ramlogan, Is there a trade-off between income
inequality and corruption? Evidence from Latin America
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Luís Alberiko Gil-Alana, Further evidence on the
PPP analysis of the Australian dollar: non-linearities, structural changes and
fractional integration
Estefanía Mourelle and Juan Carlos Cuestas, Inflation persistence and
asymmetries: Evidence for African countries
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Barry Harrison, Further evidence on the real
interest rate parity hypothesis in Central and Eastern European Countries:
unit roots and nonlinearities
Simeon Coleman, Inflation persistence in the Franc Zone: evidence from
disaggregated prices
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Paulo Regis, Nonlinearities and the order of
2010/3
2010/2
2010/1
2009/7
2009/6
2009/5
2009/4
2009/3
2009/2
2009/1
2008/16
2008/15
and public agendas: testing for media effects in Argentina Turing the
Kirchner administration
Vitor Leone, From property companies to real estate investment trusts: the
impact of economic and property factors in the UK commercial property
returns
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Paulo José Regis, Purchasing power parity in OECD
countries: nonlinear unit root tests revisited
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Bruce Philp, Exploitation and the class struggle
Barry Harrison and Winston Moore, Nonlinearities in Stock Returns for Some
Recent Entrants to the EU
Joao R. Faria, Le Wang and Zhongmin Wu, Debts on debts
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Luis A. Gil-Alana, Unemployment hysteresis,
structural changes,non-linearities and fractional integration in Central and
Eastern Europe
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Javier Ordóñez, Unemployment and common
smooth transition trends in Central and Eastern European Countries
Stephen Dobson and Carlyn Ramlogan, Is there a trade-off between income
inequality and corruption? Evidence from Latin America
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Luís Alberiko Gil-Alana, Further evidence on the
PPP analysis of the Australian dollar: non-linearities, structural changes and
fractional integration
Estefanía Mourelle and Juan Carlos Cuestas, Inflation persistence and
asymmetries: Evidence for African countries
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Barry Harrison, Further evidence on the real
interest rate parity hypothesis in Central and Eastern European Countries:
unit roots and nonlinearities
Simeon Coleman, Inflation persistence in the Franc Zone: evidence from
disaggregated prices
Juan Carlos Cuestas and Paulo Regis, Nonlinearities and the order of
process? Smooth transitions, nonlinear trends and unit root testing
2008/11 Antonio Rodriguez Andres and Carlyn Ramlogan-Dobson, Corruption,
privatisation and the distribution of income in Latin America
2008/10 Stephen Dobson and Carlyn Ramlogan, Is there an openness Kuznets
curve? Evidence from Latin America
2008/9 Stephen Dobson, John Goddard and Frank Stähler, Effort levels in contests:
an empirical application of the Tullock model
2008/8 Juan Carlos Cuestas and Estefania Mourelle, Nonlinearities in real exchange
rate determination: Do African exchange rates follow a random walk?
2008/7 Stephen Dobson and John Goddard, Strategic behaviour and risk taking in
football
2008/6 Joao Ricardo Faria, Juan Carlos Cuestas and Estefania Mourelle,
Entrepreneurship and unemployment: A nonlinear bidirectional causality?
2008/5 Dan Wheatley, Irene Hardill and Bruce Philp, “Managing” reductions in
working hours: A study of work-time and leisure preferences in the UK
industry
2008/4 Adrian Kay and Robert Ackrill, Institutional change in the international
governance of agriculture: a revised account
2008/3 Juan Carlos Cuestas and Paulo José Regis, Testing for PPP in Australia:
Evidence from unit root test against nonlinear trend stationarity alternatives
2008/2 João Ricardo Faria, Juan Carlos Cuestas and Luis Gil-Alana, Unemployment
and entrepreneurship: A Cyclical Relation
2008/1 Zhongmin Wu, Mark Baimbridge and Yu Zhu, Multiple Job Holding in the
United Kingdom: Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey
DISCUSSION PAPERS IN POLITICAL ECONOMY
2008/11 Antonio Rodriguez Andres and Carlyn Ramlogan-Dobson, Corruption,
privatisation and the distribution of income in Latin America
2008/10 Stephen Dobson and Carlyn Ramlogan, Is there an openness Kuznets
curve? Evidence from Latin America
2008/9 Stephen Dobson, John Goddard and Frank Stähler, Effort levels in contests:
an empirical application of the Tullock model
2008/8 Juan Carlos Cuestas and Estefania Mourelle, Nonlinearities in real exchange
rate determination: Do African exchange rates follow a random walk?
2008/7 Stephen Dobson and John Goddard, Strategic behaviour and risk taking in
football
2008/6 Joao Ricardo Faria, Juan Carlos Cuestas and Estefania Mourelle,
Entrepreneurship and unemployment: A nonlinear bidirectional causality?
2008/5 Dan Wheatley, Irene Hardill and Bruce Philp, “Managing” reductions in
working hours: A study of work-time and leisure preferences in the UK
industry
2008/4 Adrian Kay and Robert Ackrill, Institutional change in the international
governance of agriculture: a revised account
2008/3 Juan Carlos Cuestas and Paulo José Regis, Testing for PPP in Australia:
Evidence from unit root test against nonlinear trend stationarity alternatives
2008/2 João Ricardo Faria, Juan Carlos Cuestas and Luis Gil-Alana, Unemployment
and entrepreneurship: A Cyclical Relation
2008/1 Zhongmin Wu, Mark Baimbridge and Yu Zhu, Multiple Job Holding in the
United Kingdom: Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey
DISCUSSION PAPERS IN POLITICAL ECONOMY
Investment and Labour Commanded
2004/1 David Harvie, Value-Production and Struggle in the Classroom, or, Educators Within,
Against and Beyond Capital
DISCUSSION PAPERS IN APPLIED ECONOMICS AND POLICY
2007/2 Juan Carlos Cuestas, Purchasing Power Parity in Central and Eastern
European Countries: An Analysis of Unit Roots and Non-linearities
2007/1 Juan Carlos Cuestas and Javier Ordóñez, Testing for Price Convergence
among Mercosur Countries
2006/2 Rahmi Cetin and Robert Ackrill, Foreign Investment and the Export of
Foreign and Local Firms: An Analysis of Turkish Manufacturing
2006/1 Robert Ackrill and Adrian Kay, The EU Financial Perspective 2007-2013 and
the Forces that Shaped the Final Agreement
2004/5 Michael A. Smith, David Paton and Leighton Vaughan-Williams, Costs,
Biases and Betting markets: New evidence
2004/4 Chris Forde and Gary Slater, Agency Working in Britain: Character,
Consequences and Regulation
2004/3 Barry Harrison and David Paton, Do „Fat Tails‟ Matter in GARCH Estimation?
Stock market efficiency in Romania and the Czech Republic
2004/2 Dean Garratt and Rebecca Taylor, Issue-based Teaching in Economics
2004/1 Michael McCann, Motives for Acquisitions in the UK
2003/6 Chris Forde and Gary Slater, The Nature and Experience of Agency Working
in Britain
2003/5 Eugen Mihaita, Generating Hypothetical Rates of Return for the Romanian
Fully Funded Pension Funds
2003/4 Eugen Mihaita, The Romanian Pension Reform
2004/1 David Harvie, Value-Production and Struggle in the Classroom, or, Educators Within,
Against and Beyond Capital
DISCUSSION PAPERS IN APPLIED ECONOMICS AND POLICY
2007/2 Juan Carlos Cuestas, Purchasing Power Parity in Central and Eastern
European Countries: An Analysis of Unit Roots and Non-linearities
2007/1 Juan Carlos Cuestas and Javier Ordóñez, Testing for Price Convergence
among Mercosur Countries
2006/2 Rahmi Cetin and Robert Ackrill, Foreign Investment and the Export of
Foreign and Local Firms: An Analysis of Turkish Manufacturing
2006/1 Robert Ackrill and Adrian Kay, The EU Financial Perspective 2007-2013 and
the Forces that Shaped the Final Agreement
2004/5 Michael A. Smith, David Paton and Leighton Vaughan-Williams, Costs,
Biases and Betting markets: New evidence
2004/4 Chris Forde and Gary Slater, Agency Working in Britain: Character,
Consequences and Regulation
2004/3 Barry Harrison and David Paton, Do „Fat Tails‟ Matter in GARCH Estimation?
Stock market efficiency in Romania and the Czech Republic
2004/2 Dean Garratt and Rebecca Taylor, Issue-based Teaching in Economics
2004/1 Michael McCann, Motives for Acquisitions in the UK
2003/6 Chris Forde and Gary Slater, The Nature and Experience of Agency Working
in Britain
2003/5 Eugen Mihaita, Generating Hypothetical Rates of Return for the Romanian
Fully Funded Pension Funds
2003/4 Eugen Mihaita, The Romanian Pension Reform
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
Transition Economy: Evidence from Romania.
1 out of 32
Your All-in-One AI-Powered Toolkit for Academic Success.
+13062052269
info@desklib.com
Available 24*7 on WhatsApp / Email
Unlock your academic potential
© 2024 | Zucol Services PVT LTD | All rights reserved.