This article discusses international trade, absolute advantage, comparative advantage, production possibilities, and equilibrium price ratio. It explains how trade can benefit both countries and increase their consumption possibilities. The article provides detailed calculations and graphs to illustrate the concepts.
Contribute Materials
Your contribution can guide someone’s learning journey. Share your
documents today.
Running Head: INTERNATIONAL TRADE International Trade Name of the Student Name of the Student Author note Course ID
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
2INTERNATIONAL TRADE Answer 1 Answer a In Home country, labor hours employed to produce 1 unit of butter is 1/5 hours. The Foreign country needs to use 1 hours to produce the same. Home country has an absolute advantage in butter as it can produce it with a less labor hours compared to Foreign (Costinot et al., 2015). In Home country, 1 hours of labor is used to produce 1 unit cloth. In Foreign, 1/3 hours of labor is used to produce every unit of cloth. Foreign country has an absolute advantage in producing cloth because of requirement of less labor hours. Answer b In Home, unit butter production require 1/5 hours of labor. 5 unit of butter in the Home county requires (1/5 * 5) = 1 hour of labor. Unit cloth production in Home requires 1 hour of labor.3 unit of cloth in Foreign country requires (1*3) = 3 hours of labor. Trading 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth Home thus can save (3 – 1) = 2 hours of labor. Using this excess labor hours Home can produce additional butter (Levchenko & Zhang, 2016).Producing 3 units of cloth requires (1/3 *3) = 1 hours of labor in Foreign. Producing 5 units of butter requires (1*5) = 5 hours of labor. Trading 3 units of cloth for 5 units of butter leads to saving of (5 – 1) = 4 hours of labor. The additional labor hours in Foreign could be used to produce more cloths Answer c 5 unit of butter in the Home county requires (1/5 * 5) = 1 hour of labor. 6 unit of cloth in Home country requires (1*6) = 6 hours of labor. Trading 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth Home thus can save (6 – 1) = 5hours of labor. Producing 5 units of butter requires (1*5) = 5
3INTERNATIONAL TRADE hours of labor. Producing 6 units of cloth requires (1/3 *6) = 2 hours of labor in Foreign. Trading 3 units of cloth for 5 units of butter leads to saving of (5 – 2) = 3 hours of labor. Answer 2 Answer a Figure 1: Production Possibilities (Home)
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
4INTERNATIONAL TRADE Figure 2: Production Possibilities (Foreign) Answer b Given that, 5 hours of labor is necessary to produce 1 Motorbike and that of 2 hours of labor is necessary to produce 1 Skateboard, the relative price of Motorbikes to Skateboard is PM PS =aLM aLS ¿5 2 ¿2.5 In Foreign, the relative price ratio of Motorbike to Skateboard is (PM PS)¿ =aLM ¿ aLS ¿ ¿3 3 ¿1 Answer c Aftertrade,eachnationspecializesandproducesgoodsinfavorofcomparative advantage. As country focuses on production of only one specialized good, resources are utilized in better way as compared to autarky position where countries need to distribute the available resources among all the goods (Borkakoti, 2017). As each nation produces only specialized goods, a large amount of goods is produced with available resources. The increased range of production expands the choice of consumption as well.
5INTERNATIONAL TRADE Home uses 5 hours of labor to produce 1 motorbike and it uses 2 hours of labor to produce1 skateboard. The production of 1 motorbike thus requires sacrifice of (5/2) = 2.5 Skateboards. The opportunity cost of Motorbike relative to Skateboard in Home thus is 2.5 of Skateboard. Foreign uses 3 hours of labor to produce 1 motorbike and it uses 3 hours of labor to produce1skateboard.Theproductionof1motorbikethusrequiressacrificeof(3/3)= 1Skateboards.In Foreign the opportunity cost of Motorbikes in terms of Skateboard is 1 Skateboard (Chacholiades, 2017).Foreign has a smaller opportunity cost for production of Motorbike and hence, enjoys a comparative advantage in Motorbike. The opportunity cost of Skateboard in Home equals (2/5) = 0.4 Motorbikes. The same in Foreign equals (3/3) = 1 Motorbike. In case of Skateboard, Home has a lower opportunity cost and hence, has a comparative advantage in Skateboard. After trade Home country would specialize in producing Skateboard while foreign country would specialize in Motorbikes. In Home country, the relative price of Skateboard in terms of Motorbike is the opportunity cost of Skateboard that is (2/5).In Foreign country, relative price of Skateboard to Motorbike is (3/3) = 1. In the world market, the relative price of Skateboard must be between the ratios of relative prices in the two nation (French, 2016). Under free trade, relative price of Skateboard to Motorbike is given as 4/5. The given world relative price is within relative price ratios under autarky in Home and Foreign. Each nation thus would produce goods in line with the comparative advantage. In the Home country, available total labor hours is 1000 hours. The maximum labor hours that Home country could utilize thus is LH=1000. Home requires 2 hours of labor to produce 1 Skateboard. The unit labor requirement thus isaLS= 2 hours. Using all the endowed labor hours Home thus is able to produce a total
6INTERNATIONAL TRADE S=LH aLS ¿1000 2 ¿500Skateboard The relative price of Skateboard in world market is given as 4/5. Following the world relative price, 1 Skateboard is traded for 4/5 Motorbikes. Therefore, Home can exchange 500 Skateboard for (4/5 * 500) = 400 Motorbikes. Before trade,Home needs to produce both Motorbike and Skateboard (Laursen, 2015). The available labor hours are thus divided between Skateboard and Motorbikes. aLMM+aLSS=LH ¿,5M+2S=1000 If Home produces only Motorbikes, then maximum number of produced Motorbike would be 200 If Home produces only Skateboard, then maximum number of produced Motorbike would be 500 After trade,given the world relative price ratio, Home can trade 500 Skateboards in exchange of 400 Skateboard. The available Motorbikes for consumption in Home country after trade thus increases from 200 to 400 Motorbikes (Dix‐Carneiro, 2014). The figure below shows the consumption possibility frontier for Home country before and after trade.
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
7INTERNATIONAL TRADE Figure 3: Consumption Possibilities in Home In Foreign country, available total labor hours is 1200 hours. The maximum labor hours that Home country could utilize thus is LH=1200. Foreign requires 3 hours of labor to produce 1 Motorbike. The unit labor requirement thus isaLM*= 3 hours. Using all the endowed labor hours Foreign thus is able to produce a total S=LH aLM ¿ ¿1200 3 ¿400Motorbikes The relative price of Skateboard in world market is given as 4/5. Following the world relative price,
8INTERNATIONAL TRADE 1 Motorbike is traded for 5/4 Skateboard. Therefore, Foreign can exchange 400 Motorbikes for (5/4 * 400) = 500 Skateboard. Before trade,Home needs to produce both Motorbike and Skateboard. The available labor hours are thus divided between Skateboard and Motorbikes. aLM ¿M+aLS ¿S=LH ¿,3M+3S=1200 If Foreign produces only Motorbikes, then maximum number of produced Motorbike would be 400 If Foreign produces only Skateboard, then maximum number of produced Motorbike would be 400 After trade,given the world relative price ratio, Foreign can trade 400 Motorbikes in exchange of 500 Skateboard. The available Skateboard for consumption in foreign country after trade thus increases from 400 to 500 Skateboard (Cosar & Fajgelbaum, 2016). The figure below shows the consumption possibility frontier for foreign country before and after trade.
9INTERNATIONAL TRADE Figure 4: Consumption Possibilities in Foreign
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
10INTERNATIONAL TRADE Answer 3 Answer a A country enjoys an absolute advantage if it is capable of producing a good at a lower absolute cost in relation to other country. In H, 1 unit of X is produced using 6 labor. The amount of labor employed in F to produce 1 unit of X 4. One country conquers an absolute advantage over another nation if it requires fewer resources in unit production of the good (Watson, 2017). The country F here requires fewer labor (4 < 6) to produce 1 unit of X. The economy of F is thus identified as to have an absolute advantage in producing X. 1 unit of Y production in the country H demands 12 units of labor. The same in the country F demands 2 units’ labor. In case of Y again, F needs a lesser labor hours compared to H. F thus has an absolute advantage in Y. Consequently, F has an absolute advantage in making both X and Y. One country has a comparative advantage over other it production of the specific goods has a relatively lower opportunity cost to other (Jaimovich & Merella, 2015). In the country H, Unit production of X needs 6 labors while unit production of Y needs 12 labors. The opportunity cost of X in H thus equals (6/12) = ½ unit of Y. That is to produce 1 unit of X, H needs to forgo ½ unit of Y. In F, 1-unit production of X needs 4 unit of labor while 1 unit of Y needs 2 unit of labor. The opportunity cost of 1 unit of X in F equals (4/2) = 2 unit of Y. The relatively low opportunity cost in for X in H indicates the country has a comparative advantage in X.In country H, producing 1 unit of Y requires to forgo (12/6) = 2 units of X. In F, production of 1 unit of Y requires to forgo (2/4) = ½ unit of X. In F thus opportunity cost of Y is lower compared to that in country H. Hence, F has a comparative advantage in making Y. Answer b
11INTERNATIONAL TRADE The total available labors in country H is 2400 units. Country H requires 6 units of labor to produce 1 unit of X. Therefore, if country H produces only labor then it can produce a total of (2400/6) = 400 units of X. 1 unit of Y production in H requires 12 labors. Hence, if H produces only Y, then it is able to produce a total of (2400/12) = 200 units of Y. The production possibility frontier for economy H is thus bounded by the maximum production of X and Y (Krugman, Obstfeld & Melitz, 2015). Figure 5: Production Possibility (H) Country F in total has 1800 units of labor. Country F employs 4 units of labor to produce 1 unit of X. Therefore, if country F produces only labor then it can produce a total of (1800/4) = 450 units of X. 1 unit of Y production in F requires 2 labors. Hence, if F produces only Y, then it is able to produce a total of (1800/2) = 900 units of Y. The production possibility frontier for economy F is thus bounded by the maximum production of X and Y.
12INTERNATIONAL TRADE Figure 5: Production Possibility (F) In the absence of trade, the relative price of the goods in each country is same as the opportunity cost of making the good. This is because, in autarky equilibrium arises at the point where cost of producing good equals to the purchasing cost of the same. Equilibrium price ratio is autarky in the country H is determined as PX PY =6 12 ¿1 2 ¿0.5 In the country F, the autarky equilibrium price ratio is computed as (PX PY)¿ =4 2
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
13INTERNATIONAL TRADE ¿2 Answer c The standard trade theory suggests that for trade to occur, the relative price in the international market should be between the relative prices of the goods without trade (Gandolfo, 2014). The autarky relative price of X in H is obtained as ½. The relative price of X in F is obtained as 2. The world price thus should be in between ½ and 2. The range of feasible equilibrium world price ratios is given as (PX PY)<(PX PY) W <(PX PY)¿ 1 2<(PX PY)W <2 Answer d Country F has an absolute advantage in making both X and Y. The theory of absolute advantage thus fails to predict any pattern of trade between H and F. Direction of trade is thus determined following the theory of comparative advantage. The comparative advantage theory determines the trade pattern depending on the opportunity cost of production (Holmes & Stevens, 2014). The opportunity cost of X in country H is equivalent to ½ unit of Y. In country F, the opportunity cost of production of X equals 2 units of Y. Country H thus requires to sacrifice lesser unit of Y to produce 1 unit of X. Country H thus enjoys an comparative advantage in producing X. Following the theory of comparative advantage, a country should specialize and export good with lower opportunity cost (Uhlig, 2017). Country H thus should export X as it has a comparative advantage in X.
14INTERNATIONAL TRADE Answer e The Ricardian model of comparative advantage, with zero transportation cost and absence of tariff, prices of output are equalized. Wages which is the return to labor are not equalized. Return to labor reflects the productivity of labor. As productivity differs between the two trading nations, wages are not equalized. Trade increases price of the exported goods raising wages in sectors producing the exportable good. It does not howeverequalize wage among trading nations. Price at equilibrium is determined from the world relative supply and world relative demand (Baier, Bergstrand & Feng, 2014). Since, factor price are not determined by relative demand and relative supply, they are not equalized. In each nation wage is equivalent to the labor productivity. The assumption of perfect competition implies that Pi = ACi, where i denotes positive output (Burstein & Vogel, 2017). In the given example, H specializes in X while F specializes in Y. Suppose, wage in the country H is denoted as w and that in F is given as w*. PX=aLX×w ¿aLXw PY∗¿aLY ¿×w∗¿ ¿aLY ¿w∗¿ W W∗¿=PX PY∗¿×aLY ¿ aLX ¿ ¿ ≠1¿
15INTERNATIONAL TRADE List of References Baier, S. L., Bergstrand, J. H., & Feng, M. (2014). Economic integration agreements and the margins of international trade.Journal of International Economics,93(2), 339-350. Borkakoti, J. (2017).International trade: causes and consequences. Macmillan International Higher Education. Burstein, A., & Vogel, J. (2017). International trade, technology, and the skill premium.Journal of Political Economy,125(5), 1356-1412. Chacholiades, M. (2017).The pure theory of international trade. Routledge. Cosar, A. K., & Fajgelbaum, P. D. (2016). Internal geography, international trade, and regional specialization.American Economic Journal: Microeconomics,8(1), 24-56. Costinot, A., Donaldson, D., Vogel, J., & Werning, I. (2015). Comparative advantage and optimal trade policy.The Quarterly Journal of Economics,130(2), 659-702. Dix‐Carneiro, R. (2014). Trade liberalization and labor market dynamics.Econometrica,82(3), 825-885. French,S.(2016).Thecompositionoftradeflowsandtheaggregateeffectsoftrade barriers.Journal of international Economics,98, 114-137. Gandolfo, G. (2014). International Trade and Growth: Dynamics. InInternational Trade Theory and Policy(pp. 321-327). Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. Holmes, T. J., & Stevens, J. J. (2014). An alternative theory of the plant size distribution, with geography and intra-and international trade.Journal of Political Economy,122(2), 369- 421.
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
16INTERNATIONAL TRADE Jaimovich,E.,&Merella,V.(2015).Loveforquality,comparativeadvantage,and trade.Journal of International Economics,97(2), 376-391. Krugman, P., Obstfeld, M., & Melitz, M. (2015).International Trade: Theory and Policy: Global Edition. Pearson Higher Ed. Laursen, K. (2015). Revealed comparative advantage and the alternatives as measures of international specialization.Eurasian Business Review,5(1), 99-115. Levchenko, A. A., & Zhang, J. (2016). The evolution of comparative advantage: Measurement and welfare implications.Journal of Monetary Economics,78, 96-111. Uhlig,H.(2017).BusinessCyclesandInternationalTrade.JournalofPolitical Economy,125(6), 1761-1766. Watson, M. (2017). Historicising Ricardo’s comparative advantage theory, challenging the normativefoundationsofliberalInternationalPoliticalEconomy.NewPolitical Economy,22(3), 257-272.