International Trade: Absolute and Comparative Advantage, Ricardian Model
VerifiedAdded on 2023/06/08
|13
|2763
|483
AI Summary
This article discusses the concepts of absolute and comparative advantage in international trade, using hypothetical situations and unit labour requirements. It also explores the Ricardian Model and its implications on production possibility frontier, autarky equilibrium price ratio, feasible equilibrium world price ratios, and real returns to labour.
Contribute Materials
Your contribution can guide someone’s learning journey. Share your
documents today.
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/99474320-e09f-4766-a629-7422c7947ffb-page-1.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 1
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR)
Student Name
Institution Affiliation
Facilitator
Course
Date
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR)
Student Name
Institution Affiliation
Facilitator
Course
Date
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/cfe0d8d5-335f-4dcb-b9f0-84db70071419-page-2.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 2
Question 1: Absolute and Comparative Advantage (5 marks)
Consider the following hypothetical situation, described in the table, showing unit labour
requirements:
Butter Cloth
Home 1/5 (hours) 1 (hours)
Foreign 1 (hours) 1/3 (hours)
a. In which commodity does Home have an absolute advantage? In which commodity does
Foreign have an absolute advantage? Why?
b. How much will Home gain if it trades 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth? How much would
foreign gain from the same trade? Why?
c. How much will Home gain if it trades 5 units of butter for 6 units of cloth? How much would
foreign gain from the same trade?
Short Answers
a) Home has an absolute advantage in producing butter. Foreign has an absolute advantage in
producing cloth (Dornbusch, Fischer, and Samuelson, 2017, p.830).
b) If home trades 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth, home will gain 2 unit hours of butter.
From this trade, foreign will gain 3 unit hours of cloth (Greenwood, Hanson and Stein, 2015,
p.1685).
c) If home trades 5 units of butter for 6 units of cloth, home will gain 5 unit hours of butter. From
this trade, foreign will gain 3 unit hours of cloth (Hanson, Lind and Muendler, 2015)
Explanation:
a) Home has an absolute advantage in producing butter because it takes fewer hours (1/5hours)
to produce a unit of butter than foreign which takes (1hour). Foreign has an absolute advantage
Question 1: Absolute and Comparative Advantage (5 marks)
Consider the following hypothetical situation, described in the table, showing unit labour
requirements:
Butter Cloth
Home 1/5 (hours) 1 (hours)
Foreign 1 (hours) 1/3 (hours)
a. In which commodity does Home have an absolute advantage? In which commodity does
Foreign have an absolute advantage? Why?
b. How much will Home gain if it trades 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth? How much would
foreign gain from the same trade? Why?
c. How much will Home gain if it trades 5 units of butter for 6 units of cloth? How much would
foreign gain from the same trade?
Short Answers
a) Home has an absolute advantage in producing butter. Foreign has an absolute advantage in
producing cloth (Dornbusch, Fischer, and Samuelson, 2017, p.830).
b) If home trades 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth, home will gain 2 unit hours of butter.
From this trade, foreign will gain 3 unit hours of cloth (Greenwood, Hanson and Stein, 2015,
p.1685).
c) If home trades 5 units of butter for 6 units of cloth, home will gain 5 unit hours of butter. From
this trade, foreign will gain 3 unit hours of cloth (Hanson, Lind and Muendler, 2015)
Explanation:
a) Home has an absolute advantage in producing butter because it takes fewer hours (1/5hours)
to produce a unit of butter than foreign which takes (1hour). Foreign has an absolute advantage
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/5d1046d5-adf1-4656-9176-05ce2fcbf748-page-3.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 3
in producing cloth because it takes fewer hours (1/3hours) to produce a unit of cloth than home
which takes (1hour) (Costinot, Donaldson, Vogel, and Werning, 2015, p.670).
b) If home trades 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth, home will gain 2 unit hours of butter
(Vovchenko and Zhang, 2016, p.100). This is due to the fact that it will take home 1 hour to
produce 5 units of butter but it will it 3 hours to produce 3 units of cloth, hence 2 hours gain.
From this trade, foreign will gain 4 unit hours of cloth. This is due to the fact that it will take
foreign 1 hour to produce 3 units of cloth but it takes it 5 hours to produce 5 units of butter hence
4 hours gain (Costinot and Donaldson, 2017, p.12).
c) If home trades 5 units of butter for 6 units of cloth, home will gain 5 unit hours of butter
(Laursen, 2015, p.110). This is due to the fact that it will take home 1 hour to produce 5 units of
butter but it takes foreign 6 hours to produce 6 units of cloth hence 5 hours gain. From this trade,
foreign will gain 3 unit hours of cloth since it takes foreign 2 hours to produce 6 units of cloth
but it takes it 5 hours to produce 5 units of butter hence 3 hours gain (Dellas, 2017, p.130).
Question 2: The Ricardian Model (15 marks)
Consider the following hypothetical situation, described in the table, showing unit labour
requirements:
Motorbikes Skateboards
Home 5 (hours) 2 (hours)
Foreign 3 (hours) 3 (hours)
HOME has 1000 hours of labour available. FOREIGN has 1200 hours of labour available.
a. Draw the production possibility frontier for Home and Foreign.
in producing cloth because it takes fewer hours (1/3hours) to produce a unit of cloth than home
which takes (1hour) (Costinot, Donaldson, Vogel, and Werning, 2015, p.670).
b) If home trades 5 units of butter for 3 units of cloth, home will gain 2 unit hours of butter
(Vovchenko and Zhang, 2016, p.100). This is due to the fact that it will take home 1 hour to
produce 5 units of butter but it will it 3 hours to produce 3 units of cloth, hence 2 hours gain.
From this trade, foreign will gain 4 unit hours of cloth. This is due to the fact that it will take
foreign 1 hour to produce 3 units of cloth but it takes it 5 hours to produce 5 units of butter hence
4 hours gain (Costinot and Donaldson, 2017, p.12).
c) If home trades 5 units of butter for 6 units of cloth, home will gain 5 unit hours of butter
(Laursen, 2015, p.110). This is due to the fact that it will take home 1 hour to produce 5 units of
butter but it takes foreign 6 hours to produce 6 units of cloth hence 5 hours gain. From this trade,
foreign will gain 3 unit hours of cloth since it takes foreign 2 hours to produce 6 units of cloth
but it takes it 5 hours to produce 5 units of butter hence 3 hours gain (Dellas, 2017, p.130).
Question 2: The Ricardian Model (15 marks)
Consider the following hypothetical situation, described in the table, showing unit labour
requirements:
Motorbikes Skateboards
Home 5 (hours) 2 (hours)
Foreign 3 (hours) 3 (hours)
HOME has 1000 hours of labour available. FOREIGN has 1200 hours of labour available.
a. Draw the production possibility frontier for Home and Foreign.
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/95f990a1-4589-4a44-8055-0e93b3d96cb7-page-4.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 4
b. In the absence of trade, what is the relative price of motorbikes in terms of skateboards in
each country?
c. Draw the world production possibility frontier clearly showing the case of specialization in
comparative advantage and comparative disadvantage.
d. Trade is believed to make each country better off by enlarging the range of consumption
choices available to residents/consumers. Compare the consumption possibilities available to
Home and Foreign consumers in the closed economy and, in the open/trading economy cases.
Graph the expanded consumption opportunities. The relative price of skateboards in terms
of motorbikes under free trade is given and equal to 4/5.
Answers
a)
b. In the absence of trade, what is the relative price of motorbikes in terms of skateboards in
each country?
c. Draw the world production possibility frontier clearly showing the case of specialization in
comparative advantage and comparative disadvantage.
d. Trade is believed to make each country better off by enlarging the range of consumption
choices available to residents/consumers. Compare the consumption possibilities available to
Home and Foreign consumers in the closed economy and, in the open/trading economy cases.
Graph the expanded consumption opportunities. The relative price of skateboards in terms
of motorbikes under free trade is given and equal to 4/5.
Answers
a)
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/3701fecf-3146-4232-a069-a8ee0e783b7c-page-5.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 5
b) In absence of trade, the price of either bicycle or skateboard is determined by the number of
hours spend in production (Ethier, 2017, p.185). This means that, the price of bicycles in home
nation will be 5 while price for skateboards will be 3. On the other hand, price of both bicycles
and skateboards will be 3 each in foreign nation.
c) In order to maximize the production, Home should use all hours to produce skateboards while
Foreign should spend all hours to produce bicycles (Hamamatsu, 2018, p.210).
Therefore, Home 8 hours on skateboards
Foreign 6 hours on bicycles
This will translate into shared demand (Taylor, 2017, p.120). That is, people living in home will
purchase bicycles from foreign nation while buy skateboards from Home country. This
specialization scenario will maximize the returns in both nations increasing the comparative
advantage (Taylor, 2013, p.230).
The curve will look like shown below,
b) In absence of trade, the price of either bicycle or skateboard is determined by the number of
hours spend in production (Ethier, 2017, p.185). This means that, the price of bicycles in home
nation will be 5 while price for skateboards will be 3. On the other hand, price of both bicycles
and skateboards will be 3 each in foreign nation.
c) In order to maximize the production, Home should use all hours to produce skateboards while
Foreign should spend all hours to produce bicycles (Hamamatsu, 2018, p.210).
Therefore, Home 8 hours on skateboards
Foreign 6 hours on bicycles
This will translate into shared demand (Taylor, 2017, p.120). That is, people living in home will
purchase bicycles from foreign nation while buy skateboards from Home country. This
specialization scenario will maximize the returns in both nations increasing the comparative
advantage (Taylor, 2013, p.230).
The curve will look like shown below,
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/8e5bf348-281d-4de9-b816-0db8682b5002-page-6.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 6
d.) In a closed economy, foreign nation has the capacity to produce many bicycles and
skateboards quickly (Obstfeld, Rogoff and Wren, 2016). This is evidenced by the number of
hours it takes to manufacture a skateboard or bicycle. However, the Home nation is
disadvantaged; it takes more hours to manufacture a bicycle. Therefore, consumption
possibilities in home nation will be more towards skateboards since they are easy to manufacture
and hence cheap (Venables, 2017, p.710).
d.) In a closed economy, foreign nation has the capacity to produce many bicycles and
skateboards quickly (Obstfeld, Rogoff and Wren, 2016). This is evidenced by the number of
hours it takes to manufacture a skateboard or bicycle. However, the Home nation is
disadvantaged; it takes more hours to manufacture a bicycle. Therefore, consumption
possibilities in home nation will be more towards skateboards since they are easy to manufacture
and hence cheap (Venables, 2017, p.710).
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/bb3aa92d-57d0-42f9-9d38-36ea0c878348-page-7.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 7
Question 3: The Ricardian Model (20 Marks)
Suppose two economies H and F produce two goods, X and Y, with only one input: labour.
Production technology implies that unit labour requirements are given in the following table:
amount of
labour
per unit of
output
X Y
H 6 12
F 4 2
Suppose that H has 2400 units of labour and F has 1800 units of labour.
Question 3: The Ricardian Model (20 Marks)
Suppose two economies H and F produce two goods, X and Y, with only one input: labour.
Production technology implies that unit labour requirements are given in the following table:
amount of
labour
per unit of
output
X Y
H 6 12
F 4 2
Suppose that H has 2400 units of labour and F has 1800 units of labour.
Paraphrase This Document
Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/d06e526a-b23f-4a5f-82cb-8fac9d5207c2-page-8.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 8
(a) What is the pattern of absolute advantage? Of comparative advantage? Give a brief
explanation
(b) Derive the Production Possibilities Frontier (PPF) for H and F. What is the autarky
equilibrium price ratio in each country?
(c) What is the range of feasible equilibrium world price ratios?
(d) Suppose these countries trade with each other at some feasible world price ratio. Which
country exports good X? Why?
(e) Does trade equalize the real return to labour in Home and Foreign? Why?
Answer
As given, economy H needs 6 units of labour for 1 unit of X and 12 units of labour for 1 unit of
Y, having 2400 units of labour in total. While, economy F needs 4 units of labour for 1 unit of X
and 2 units of labour for 1 unit of Y, having 1800 units of labour in total.
(a) The country exporting good X will be the country having comparative advantage of X over
Y. Again, F has absolute advantage over both commodities (Weder, 2017, p.80). But because the
comparative advantage of a commodity refers to lesser relative price of the commodity, as
calculated according to autarky, the relative price of X is or 0.5 in H while is 2 in F, hence, H
have comparative advantage of producing X over Y.
(b) For economy H, the production possibility frontier (PPF) will have y-intercept at point if all
labour is producing Y, ie while x-intercept at point if all labour is producing X,
ie . For economy F, the production possibility frontier (PPF) will have y-intercept at
point if all labour is producing Y, ie while x-intercept at point if all labour is
producing X, ie ((Taylor, 2017, p.120). The equation will be linear, as since there is
(a) What is the pattern of absolute advantage? Of comparative advantage? Give a brief
explanation
(b) Derive the Production Possibilities Frontier (PPF) for H and F. What is the autarky
equilibrium price ratio in each country?
(c) What is the range of feasible equilibrium world price ratios?
(d) Suppose these countries trade with each other at some feasible world price ratio. Which
country exports good X? Why?
(e) Does trade equalize the real return to labour in Home and Foreign? Why?
Answer
As given, economy H needs 6 units of labour for 1 unit of X and 12 units of labour for 1 unit of
Y, having 2400 units of labour in total. While, economy F needs 4 units of labour for 1 unit of X
and 2 units of labour for 1 unit of Y, having 1800 units of labour in total.
(a) The country exporting good X will be the country having comparative advantage of X over
Y. Again, F has absolute advantage over both commodities (Weder, 2017, p.80). But because the
comparative advantage of a commodity refers to lesser relative price of the commodity, as
calculated according to autarky, the relative price of X is or 0.5 in H while is 2 in F, hence, H
have comparative advantage of producing X over Y.
(b) For economy H, the production possibility frontier (PPF) will have y-intercept at point if all
labour is producing Y, ie while x-intercept at point if all labour is producing X,
ie . For economy F, the production possibility frontier (PPF) will have y-intercept at
point if all labour is producing Y, ie while x-intercept at point if all labour is
producing X, ie ((Taylor, 2017, p.120). The equation will be linear, as since there is
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/e387ef91-d646-4177-a68a-98e3f3017131-page-9.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 9
no capital, the cost of increasing output at the PPF curve will be constant. Now, remember that to
find a linear equation with two variables by two given points and , will have the
slope , and equation , for C be y intercept at X=0 ((Taylor, 2017, p.121).
Hence, for economy H, we have the points as (0,200) and (400,0) as the intercept's coordinate,
and hence , will have the equation For
economy F, we have the points as (0,900) and (450,0) as the intercept's coordinate, and hence
, will have the equation .
The graphs are as below (graphed is scaled as x from 0 to 500 and y from 0 to 1000)
(Hamamatsu, 2018, p.210).
no capital, the cost of increasing output at the PPF curve will be constant. Now, remember that to
find a linear equation with two variables by two given points and , will have the
slope , and equation , for C be y intercept at X=0 ((Taylor, 2017, p.121).
Hence, for economy H, we have the points as (0,200) and (400,0) as the intercept's coordinate,
and hence , will have the equation For
economy F, we have the points as (0,900) and (450,0) as the intercept's coordinate, and hence
, will have the equation .
The graphs are as below (graphed is scaled as x from 0 to 500 and y from 0 to 1000)
(Hamamatsu, 2018, p.210).
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/1417adb9-33dd-492d-ae76-46290b6fb164-page-10.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 10
Autarky equilibrium price ratio of good X is , ie relative price of X with respect to Y. It is the
slope of the PPF, and since the slope is same as due to constant cost, we have autarky price of X
in H is , and in F is . Note, only absolute value of slope is taken to show the
relation's magnitude (Levchenko and Zhang, 2016, p.100).
(c) Range of equilibrium feasible world price ratio will be the range between the relative autarky
equilibrium prices of the two economies, ie range is , for be the world price ratio.
(d) At the feasible world price ratio the country exporting good X will be the country having
comparative advantage of X over Y. As can be seen in the graph, F has absolute advantage over
both commodities. But comparative advantage of a commodity refers to lesser relative price of
the commodity. As calculated, autarky relative price of X is or 0.5 in H while is 2 in F, hence,
H have comparative advantage of producing X over Y. Thus, H exports the good X.
(e) Real returns to labour refer to how much the workers consume in amount of commodities
(Ethier, 2017, p.185). Suppose their nominal wage is w, they would consume of X or of Y.
It can be seen as the number of X or Y the economy consumes is the number of X or Y it
produces. Since output per labour is given in the table, the labour productivity is the reciprocal of
it, and hence we can have the following table.
Real return of
labour of X of Y
Autarky equilibrium price ratio of good X is , ie relative price of X with respect to Y. It is the
slope of the PPF, and since the slope is same as due to constant cost, we have autarky price of X
in H is , and in F is . Note, only absolute value of slope is taken to show the
relation's magnitude (Levchenko and Zhang, 2016, p.100).
(c) Range of equilibrium feasible world price ratio will be the range between the relative autarky
equilibrium prices of the two economies, ie range is , for be the world price ratio.
(d) At the feasible world price ratio the country exporting good X will be the country having
comparative advantage of X over Y. As can be seen in the graph, F has absolute advantage over
both commodities. But comparative advantage of a commodity refers to lesser relative price of
the commodity. As calculated, autarky relative price of X is or 0.5 in H while is 2 in F, hence,
H have comparative advantage of producing X over Y. Thus, H exports the good X.
(e) Real returns to labour refer to how much the workers consume in amount of commodities
(Ethier, 2017, p.185). Suppose their nominal wage is w, they would consume of X or of Y.
It can be seen as the number of X or Y the economy consumes is the number of X or Y it
produces. Since output per labour is given in the table, the labour productivity is the reciprocal of
it, and hence we can have the following table.
Real return of
labour of X of Y
Secure Best Marks with AI Grader
Need help grading? Try our AI Grader for instant feedback on your assignments.
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/41c5ccde-bd70-472c-a989-a7a124f23adb-page-11.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 11
H 1/6 = 0.167 1/12 = 0.083
F 1/4 = 0.25 1/2 = 0.5
The table can also be interpreted as amount of output per unit of labour, in autarky.
After trade, the wages (real return of labour) will remain same as that of autarky for goods with
comparative advantage, but wages will depend on world price ratio for goods not produced due
to comparative disadvantage (Ethier, 2017, p.182). For this second case, the wage will be taken
as . The table is as below.
Real return of
labour of X of Y
H 1/6 = 0.167
F 1/2 = 0.5
Hence, as can be seen, the real returns of labour in H was 0.167 and 0.083, but now is 0.167
and and for . Also, the real returns of labour in F was 0.25 and 0.5,
but now is and 0.5, and for . Hence, workers are better off in both
nations producing both goods (Ethier, 2017, p.180).
H 1/6 = 0.167 1/12 = 0.083
F 1/4 = 0.25 1/2 = 0.5
The table can also be interpreted as amount of output per unit of labour, in autarky.
After trade, the wages (real return of labour) will remain same as that of autarky for goods with
comparative advantage, but wages will depend on world price ratio for goods not produced due
to comparative disadvantage (Ethier, 2017, p.182). For this second case, the wage will be taken
as . The table is as below.
Real return of
labour of X of Y
H 1/6 = 0.167
F 1/2 = 0.5
Hence, as can be seen, the real returns of labour in H was 0.167 and 0.083, but now is 0.167
and and for . Also, the real returns of labour in F was 0.25 and 0.5,
but now is and 0.5, and for . Hence, workers are better off in both
nations producing both goods (Ethier, 2017, p.180).
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/04d6b010-8edd-448b-9dfe-c13fc6bb16ea-page-12.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 12
Hence, real return to labour has increased in both nations because of trade. The actual
comparison can be made only if the world price ratio is stated, but in theory, real returns to
labour become more equal throughout the world as nations do free trade.
References
Costinot, A., Donaldson, D., Vogel, J. and Werning, I., 2015. Comparative advantage and
optimal trade policy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(2), pp.659-702.
Costinot, A. and Donaldson, D., 2017. Old idea, new insights: The Ricardian revival in
international trade. NBER Reporter, (3), pp.11-15.
Dellas, H., 2017. Discussion About “The Main Contribution of the Ricardian Trade Theory”.
In 200 Years of Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 129-132). Springer, Cham.
Dornbusch, R., Fischer, S. and Samuelson, P.A., 2017. Comparative advantage, trade, and
payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods. The American Economic
Review, 67(5), pp.823-839.
Ethier, W.J., 2017. The Relevance of Ricardian Trade Theory for the Political Economy of Trade
Policy. In 200 Years of Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 185-187). Springer, Cham.
Greenwood, R., Hanson, S.G. and Stein, J.C., 2015. A Comparative‐Advantage Approach to
Government Debt Maturity. The Journal of Finance, 70(4), pp.1683-1722.
Hisamatsu, T., 2018. Robert Torrens and the Ricardian model of dynamic equilibrium
growth. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 25(2), pp.203-226.
Hence, real return to labour has increased in both nations because of trade. The actual
comparison can be made only if the world price ratio is stated, but in theory, real returns to
labour become more equal throughout the world as nations do free trade.
References
Costinot, A., Donaldson, D., Vogel, J. and Werning, I., 2015. Comparative advantage and
optimal trade policy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(2), pp.659-702.
Costinot, A. and Donaldson, D., 2017. Old idea, new insights: The Ricardian revival in
international trade. NBER Reporter, (3), pp.11-15.
Dellas, H., 2017. Discussion About “The Main Contribution of the Ricardian Trade Theory”.
In 200 Years of Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 129-132). Springer, Cham.
Dornbusch, R., Fischer, S. and Samuelson, P.A., 2017. Comparative advantage, trade, and
payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods. The American Economic
Review, 67(5), pp.823-839.
Ethier, W.J., 2017. The Relevance of Ricardian Trade Theory for the Political Economy of Trade
Policy. In 200 Years of Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 185-187). Springer, Cham.
Greenwood, R., Hanson, S.G. and Stein, J.C., 2015. A Comparative‐Advantage Approach to
Government Debt Maturity. The Journal of Finance, 70(4), pp.1683-1722.
Hisamatsu, T., 2018. Robert Torrens and the Ricardian model of dynamic equilibrium
growth. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 25(2), pp.203-226.
![Document Page](https://desklib.com/media/document/docfile/pages/international-trade-advantage-ricardian-model/2024/09/07/cb3f8773-b802-4534-a3e7-84c547c0c00e-page-13.webp)
INTERNATIONAL TRADE (ECO3ITR/ECO2ITR) 13
Hanson, G.H., Lind, N. and Muendler, M.A., 2015. The dynamics of comparative
advantage (No. w21753). National bureau of economic research.
Levchenko, A.A. and Zhang, J., 2016. The evolution of comparative advantage: Measurement
and welfare implications. Journal of Monetary Economics, 78, pp.96-111.
Laursen, K., 2015. Revealed comparative advantage and the alternatives as measures of
international specialization. Eurasian Business Review, 5(1), pp.99-115.
Taylor, M.S., 2017. Comments on the “The Main Contribution of the Ricardian Trade Theory”
by Ronald W. Jones. In 200 Years of Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 117-127). Springer, Cham.
Taylor, M.S., 2013. ‘Quality ladders’ and Ricardian trade. Journal of International
Economics, 34(3-4), pp.225-243.
Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K.S. and Wren-lewis, S., 2016. Foundations of international
macroeconomics (Vol. 30). Cambridge, MA: MIT press.
Venables, A.J., 2017. Trade and trade policy with differentiated products: A Chamberlinian-
Ricardian model. The Economic Journal, 97(387), pp.700-717.
Weder, R., 2017. The Ricardian Trade Model: Implications and Applications. In 200 Years of
Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 73-97). Springer, Cham.
Hanson, G.H., Lind, N. and Muendler, M.A., 2015. The dynamics of comparative
advantage (No. w21753). National bureau of economic research.
Levchenko, A.A. and Zhang, J., 2016. The evolution of comparative advantage: Measurement
and welfare implications. Journal of Monetary Economics, 78, pp.96-111.
Laursen, K., 2015. Revealed comparative advantage and the alternatives as measures of
international specialization. Eurasian Business Review, 5(1), pp.99-115.
Taylor, M.S., 2017. Comments on the “The Main Contribution of the Ricardian Trade Theory”
by Ronald W. Jones. In 200 Years of Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 117-127). Springer, Cham.
Taylor, M.S., 2013. ‘Quality ladders’ and Ricardian trade. Journal of International
Economics, 34(3-4), pp.225-243.
Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K.S. and Wren-lewis, S., 2016. Foundations of international
macroeconomics (Vol. 30). Cambridge, MA: MIT press.
Venables, A.J., 2017. Trade and trade policy with differentiated products: A Chamberlinian-
Ricardian model. The Economic Journal, 97(387), pp.700-717.
Weder, R., 2017. The Ricardian Trade Model: Implications and Applications. In 200 Years of
Ricardian Trade Theory (pp. 73-97). Springer, Cham.
1 out of 13
Related Documents
![[object Object]](/_next/image/?url=%2F_next%2Fstatic%2Fmedia%2Flogo.6d15ce61.png&w=640&q=75)
Your All-in-One AI-Powered Toolkit for Academic Success.
+13062052269
info@desklib.com
Available 24*7 on WhatsApp / Email
Unlock your academic potential
© 2024 | Zucol Services PVT LTD | All rights reserved.