Australian Milk Market: Competitive Structure and Policy Essay

Verified

Added on  2022/10/13

|6
|1464
|14
Essay
AI Summary
This essay provides an in-depth analysis of the Australian milk market, arguing that it likely operates under perfect competition. The essay supports this claim by examining key characteristics such as the large number of sellers, homogeneous products, price-taking behavior, free entry and exit, perfect market knowledge, and the absence of government intervention. It further explores how the exit of milk farmers impacts market supply and prices, illustrating these effects with supply and demand graphs. The essay then delves into the concept of demand elasticity for milk, categorizing it as an inelastic good, and discusses the implications of price changes on consumer demand. Finally, the essay proposes several policy measures that could support Australian milk farmers, including the implementation of price floors and the establishment of cooperatives to enhance their market power and negotiate fairer prices. The essay concludes by referencing relevant academic literature to support its arguments.
Document Page
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY 1
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY
Student’s Name
Institution Affiliation
Course
Facilitator
Date
tabler-icon-diamond-filled.svg

Paraphrase This Document

Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
Document Page
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY 2
The Australian milk market is likely to be a perfectly competitive market where no single
seller can affect the market price (Azevedo and Gottlieb 2017, p.67). A perfectively competitive
market structure describes a market which has a vast number of buyers and sellers trading
products which are homogeneous at a single price set in the entire market. The following features
suggest a perfectly competitive market structure for the Australian milk market. Firstly, the
market is made up of a vast number of sellers. From the article, the Australian milk market
currently has 5669 dairy firms which is quite a huge number but it’s still a decrease as compared
with the year 2010 where the number of dairy farms was high at 7511. Secondly, the Australian
milk market involves the buying and selling of homogeneous products (that is milk) (Mirman,
Salgueiro and Santugini 2015). This therefore means that consumers are indifferent when it
comes to buying the Australian milk market products and they end up purchasing the product
which is sold cheaply. It therefore calls for production efficiency among the Australian dairy
farms in order to minimize production costs and maximize profits. Thirdly, the milk market
involves price taking by the dairy farmers. The Australian dairy farmers have to accept the price
offered for sale in the market by the processors and supermarkets (for example “Murray
Goulburn, Fonterra and Coles and Woolworths”). The dairy farmers have little bargaining power
in the market and therefore they have to accept the prevailing market price or else risk not selling
their milk at all. Fourthly, the Australian milk market is free for entry and exit (Geroski and
Jacquemin 2013) by dairy farmers. Dairy farmers are free to enter the industry if they can bear
the competition and leave if they make unsustainable losses. For instance, from the article, since
2010, the Australian dairy farms have exited the market due to losses decreasing the number of
Australian dairy farms from 7511 in 2010 to 5669 currently. Fifthly, the milk market involves a
perfect knowledge about the prevailing market prices by both the buyers and sellers. From the
Document Page
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY 3
article, the Australian dairy farms and customers know supermarkets sell a litre of milk for $1
and buyers know their expected return from the sale. Lastly, the Australian milk market is free
from government intervention since it has been deregulated for the last two decades. The absence
of government intervention is a strong feature of the perfectly competitive market structure and
hence the Australian milk market is likely to be a perfectly competitive market.
A milk farmer may decide to stay in the industry even if they make a loss. In the short-
run period, the total business cost is made up of the variable and fixed costs and the business
must pay its fixed costs whether it operates or not. If a business is making losses in the short-run
but its revenue is greater than its average variable costs, then it means it can pay its variable costs
and use the remaining revenue to pay all or part of its fixed costs (Mas-Colell 2014). This
therefore means, a milk farmer’s revenue exceeds his or her average variable costs and therefore
he or she can pay the variable costs and all or part of the fixed costs and therefore, he or she can
stay in the market since in the long-run he or she may end covering all the costs and even make a
profit.
Since the Australian milk market is likely to be a perfectly competitive market structure,
the graph for an individual milk farm and the milk industry has been used to explain that the exit
of some milk farmers from the industry in the long-run period will lead to an increase in milk
price. When some farmers exit the industry in the long-run period, the supply of milk in the
industry will decrease and as a result the supply curve will shift from S0 to S1 towards the left
direction. This will decrease the quantity of milk in the milk market from Q0 to Q1. As a result,
the demand for milk in the market will increase and push milk prices upwards from P0 to P1 as
indicated in the diagram below.
Document Page
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY 4
Demand elasticity for a given commodity shows how the demand for that commodity
reacts towards its price alteration (Esteves and Reggiani 2014, p.46). Demand elasticity for a
good depends on its degree of necessity. Necessity commodities are said to have inelastic
demand and their demand elasticity is less than 1 while commodities which are not necessary are
said to have elastic demand and their demand elasticity is more than 1 (Vlachos and Biskas 2013,
p.1966). Milk is usually categorized as a necessity good. This therefore means that it has an
elastic demand and its demand elasticity is less than 1 (Lumantarna et al 2010, p.487). This
therefore means a change in price for milk is likely to yield only a small change in its demand.
Therefore, a decrease in the price for milk might actually make a consumer to increase the
quantity of milk consumed but by only a small amount. In conclusion, milk has an inelastic
demand and a decrease in its price may lead to a slight increase in the quantity of milk consumed
by the consumers.
There are various policies and measures which can be used to help the Australian milk
farmers. Firstly, an introduction of price floor policy by the Australian government would help
tabler-icon-diamond-filled.svg

Paraphrase This Document

Need a fresh take? Get an instant paraphrase of this document with our AI Paraphraser
Document Page
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY 5
the milk farmers. Price floors indicate the lowest possible legal price for selling a commodity
(Bilotkach 2014, p.231). Price floors would help the Australian milk farmers to at least recover
their production costs even if it will end up regulating the unregulated industry for the last two
decades. Secondly, the Australian government should come up with programs aimed at
establishing new cooperatives. For instance, in Australian, there are only a few major processors
like Murray Goulburn, Norco and Fonterra and more than 60% of the Australian dairy farmers
supply their milk to the two processors who have been accused of anti-competitive behavior
(Aghion et al 2015, p.1). Establishment of more cooperatives would intensify competition in the
Australian dairy milk processing and this will see fair prices being offered to milk farmers.
Thirdly, the Australian milk farmers should form their association and legally register it in order
to voice their problems in unity. This will enable them to gain market power and address their
problems strongly.
Document Page
QUESTION FOUR ESSAY 6
References
Aghion, P., Cai, J., Dewatripont, M., Du, L., Harrison, A. and Legros, P., 2015. Industrial policy
and competition. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(4), pp.1-32.
Azevedo, E.M. and Gottlieb, D., 2017. Perfect competition in markets with adverse
selection. Econometrica, 85(1), pp.67-105.
Bilotkach, V., 2014. Price Floors and Quality Choice. Bulletin of Economic Research, 66(3),
pp.231-245.
Esteves, R.B. and Reggiani, C., 2014. Elasticity of demand and behaviour-based price
discrimination. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 32, pp.46-56.
Geroski, P.G. and Jacquemin, A., 2013. Barriers to entry and strategic competition. Routledge.
Lumantarna, E., Lam, N., Wilson, J. and Griffith, M., 2010. Inelastic displacement demand of
strength-degraded structures. Journal of Earthquake Engineering, 14(4), pp.487-511.
Mas-Colell, A. ed., 2014. Noncooperative approaches to the theory of perfect competition (Vol.
3). Academic Press.
Mirman, L.J., Salgueiro, E. and Santugini, M., 2015. Learning: Perfectly Competitive Market.
Vlachos, A.G. and Biskas, P.N., 2013. Demand response in a real-time balancing market clearing
with pay-as-bid pricing. IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, 4(4), pp.1966-1975.
chevron_up_icon
1 out of 6
circle_padding
hide_on_mobile
zoom_out_icon
[object Object]